Sari Mazzurco, The Law of Social Roles for the Platform Internet
Law’s expressive
function: how law tells people what social roles various institutions are
supposed to carry out. Policy discourse should explicitly consider the social
roles legal reform would construct for platforms to help public understand whether
platforms are doing what they should, guide platform behaviors, and guide
further reform. Legislation should be attuned to multiple social roles
platforms play. Social roles are fundamental: shorthand that help us understand
what behavior is appropriate or inappropriate based on relationship context. OK
to ask barista to make a latte and pay her for it, not so much for one’s PhD
advisor. Law can shape roles: set exit and entry conditions (e.g. licensing)
for roles. The roles of business and consumer have been applied flatly and
wrongly. Businesses have been assumed to be asocial; consumers are satisfying
self-interest. Businesses harm consumers only in a few ways—false advertising,
monopoly prices, defective products. But these roles support only very thin
social norms. It’s ok for businesses to do most profitable things. It’s ok for
consumers to care about price and quality, and not much else. What did FB do
wrong when sharing information with third parties when it told people it was
going to do that? Business frame obscures broader privacy harms.
A woman who feels
shame when her breastfeeding photos are taken down is not reacting as a
consumer; she is reacting as a speaker whose culturally meaningful speech has
been censored, and censorship is not a business-related concept.
Evaluates various
proposals with attention to roles, e.g. digital due process—platforms as speech
governors and users as democratic participants interested in collective and
individual autonomy, interested in accessing a wide variety of speech that
complies w/public morals. Platforms should moderate content in the public interest.
Lawmakers should enact regulations that
create
RT: (1) When you say
platform, do you mean FB? Conflating the two is common but misleading. Mike
Masnick’s test
suite is worth thinking about. (2) If FB should be democratic, why would we
accept due process in place of voting? Being the authoritarian in authoritarian
constitutionalism is a role, but is it a role you are happy with? (3) “Sir,
this is a Wendy’s” meme: mistaking a place for having a different role is
pretty common (and also correlated with racial and gender privilege). Sometimes
we just tell people that they’ve mistaken the role, even if they feel real shame/outrage
about how they’ve been treated. (4) Doug Kysar’s Preferences for Processes
is an interesting exploration of the consumer frame.
A: Any platform
could occupy multiple social roles, which help us connect harm to expectations
to behaviors. Use FB, Google and Amazon b/c those are in the press and stir up
controversy, but don’t mean to talk just about them except as monopolies.
The implications of
the various bills frame platforms in various ways, and that highlights
dimensions that may be problematic. Technological due process sounds good but
may also accept the authoritarian constitutionalism frame. [Which I think
deserves attention—if we convince enough people that the “role” of a democratic
institution is carried out by providing individuals with individual due process
on specific rulings but no ability to set the rules, that’s really bad for
democracy.] Privilege: if a person needs to know what the role of the place is,
then they do need to know what’s appropriate, and knowledge needs to be
provided by normal social channels or by law. [Fair enough, but our current
mechanisms of doing that—including law!—clearly do convey different messages to
different groups about their social status/ability to speak back/dignity
interests/etc.]
Role definitions can
render certain interpretations “irrational.” If the law says that Google is a
common carrier, expecting more speech governance is irrational. [I’m not sure
anyone is unclear on that, though—different politicians/groups just want
conflicting things from regulation and Republicans in particular are presently pushing
common carrier while Democrats are presently not.]
Sharon Sandeen: Unfair
competition is a different potential frame than either business or antitrust.
Law of warranties is another example of an apparently obvious analogy of how we
might regulate.
A: doesn’t see that
as a path forward b/c that goes to price, etc. and harms that are physical or
financial—a more holistic approach to dignity. [This is part of my “platforms
aren’t FB” hobby horse. I just don’t see Ravelry as having the same relationship
to dignitary interests.]
Jess Miers: Think
about services’ countermoves to these regulations. Removing UGC aspects of
services is often a reasonable response, not the expected “moderate
more/moderate less.”
Gary Myers, Old Wine
in New Bottles: Applying Antitrust Law’s Aspen Skiing and “Essential
Facilities” Doctrines to Address Big Tech Challenges
As an antitrust lawyer,
does antitrust have anything specific to say about the situation? Trinko case
limits idea of access to essential facilities. Aspen Skiing/essential
facilities were traditional antitrust doctrine that the SCt basically said were
possible avenues for dealing w/large firm. Trinko, dealing w/highly regulated
telecom industry, said that Verizon’s duty to deal w/competitors was governed
by complex regulatory scheme and antitrust can’t be allowed to add anything to
that. There are exceptions, which the Ct said were not overruled: Aspen
Skiing/essential facilities.
Does Aspen Skiing
indicate that a large tech firm might have duties to competitors/consumers?
Possibly yes. If monopoly power is shown, which is possible, and barriers to
entry, and significant network effects, FB might be monopoly; there are also
attempted monopolization claims which don’t require as much market power, only
a dangerous probability of success.
Likewise, essential
facilities doctrine, edging toward common carrier—firms that control
essential/important bottleneck for market participation can be required to give
access. Similar to Aspen Skiing: access requirements can be imposed. Potential First
Amendment issues, though. Business justifications are also a defense, but
usually create jury questions. In Aspen Skiing, D claimed that P’s mountain was
lower quality, which made it unworthy of cooperation; its facilities were
older/not quite as nice. Jury rejected that business justification.
Would I take this
case as an antitrust lawyer? It’s up in the air; an uphill battle partly b/c
antitrust has become so narrow and business justifications get so much weight;
having to prove each element is hard—tech cos will say they aren’t monopolies
and the market is so dynamic that things can change tomorrow. The precedent is
there despite today’s judges’ skepticism.
RT: What are the key
differences between Aspen Skiing and essential facilities that make them
different doctrines?
A: they are very
close. Essential facilities is designed to deal w/a specific kind of bottleneck—telecom,
bridge, road—a channel that’s needed. Aspen Skiing isn’t about a bottleneck but
about changing a course of dealing, doing something harmful to consumers, etc.
You could often assert both claims in parallel and Aspen did also feature an
essential facilities claim. Their general monopoly claim was stronger.
Sandeen: can you
find bad acts in terms of service especially as to businesses using the
platforms to conduct business?
A: yes, you could
definitely find problems there—restrictive terms, deplatforming, refusal to
deal on nondiscriminatory basis. Amazon’s interactions w/ 3d party sellers are possible
examples.
Tyler Ochoa: has
essential facilities ever been applied to a telecom or other company where
there could be a 1A compelled speech claim?
A: Not sure. Miami
Herald v. Tornillo is not an antitrust case [but does mention the newspaper’s
dominance in Miami, as emphasized by the recent Florida case striking down that
state’s pro-spam law].
Rosenblatt: are all
these situations (FB, Amazon) the same? This question arose w/net neutrality—access
to the underlying pipes—versus kicking someone off of Twitter. When is this a useful
tool?
A: there could be a
myriad of possible situations, which is why this area isn’t amenable to broad
brush statutory or regulatory rulemaking. Does the D have enough power for us to be
concerned? Not all tech companies have power that make their actions an
antitrust issue. Power is a big deal; secondly, is it doing something that
looks exclusionary/anticompetitive v. legit competition on the merits.
Q: As a marketing
professor, the word I say every day is Google. What are you going to do
instead, advertise on Bing? [cue laughter; I did just see a TM case entirely
about Bing, but that was probably dumb] Isn’t that an essential facility?
A: quite likely.
Access to organic results for sure, though that shouldn’t disable them from
putting sponsored ads up top.
Sandeen: a unique
dynamic online: use consumers to make the decisions about whether or not somebody
is going to be kicked off. If your ranking goes down to 1 star on FB, you get
kicked off. FB would claim that wasn’t their decision.
A: they would! They
have a case for that, too.
Jess Miers: Reddit
is now a big search engine; Tik Tok has surpassed Google.
A: it is a dynamic
market! One irony of antitrust law is its slowness.
1130:
Kristen Osenga, Can
Antitrust Learn Something from IP? (working title)
Rep. Jayapal says
that Amazon harms competition with its private labels. Collects data on sellers
and produce competing goods. 60% of overall sales according to Amazon are 3d
parties; they say only 1% is private label products. Europe has complained
about this too. Also allegedly favors its own products in search results.
What nonpublic data
are we concerned about? Sales, revenue, consumer claims/warranty claims, etc.
Lets Amazon focus retail competition on best-selling products. EU has proposed
prohibiting use of sellers’ data and prohibiting self-preferencing. The US is
following suit in proposed bills. One would prohibit self-preferencing; one
would prohibit offering both first- and third-party offerings. Amazon says this
would hurt consumers.
As an IP person, has
qualms. If something isn’t protected by IP, it’s free for copying. We like
copying! Gives consumers more choice, lower prices. We have provisions to get
generic drugs to market. Confusion is what we try to avoid, not copying. Why treat
Amazon private label products differently?
What’s really bad
here? Amazon’s ability to collect lots of data and use it to decide what
products to make; Amazon preferences itself in ads. But the same activity
happens in brick & mortar stores and no one is calling for CVS and Wal-Mart
to stop making private label goods. We know it’s riding on coattails of
national brand’s research and development and advertising. But we have
recognized their benefits when not deceptive. CVS has lots of data on sales,
when Vaseline is having sales, etc. CVS is not going to make unpopular generic
products. They are going to use the data to ensure they’re underpricing third
party sellers.
Is Amazon different
b/c of scale/type of data? You can see how long something waited in a person’s
cart or how long they spent on site. But you can get the same data if you’re
CVS on your website. Putting them side by side decreases the likelihood of
confusion.
Focusing only on
these aspects—possible that Amazon is doing really bad things.
Justin Hughes: isn’t
the answer that by all estimates Amazon controls 36-49% of ecommerce, and CVS
etc. don’t have anything like that, not even Wal-Mart? [Wal-Mart is pretty big
though in bricks & mortar.] Amazon is the bottleneck.
A: would accept the
point, but maybe market share is ok.
Hughes: but don’t
abuse your market power.
A: but what is abuse
given the benefits of data.
RT: Counterargument:
The price differential with the strong brand is empirically robust over decades
because of the consumer preference for national brands. With the current
subjects of complaint—small businesses—Amazon is the real brand driving sales
for most of these products, and so the free riding is less sustainable for a
business that doesn’t (yet) have a strong brand. If you think about
misappropriation rationales, whether the product would still be produced w/the
free riding is a consideration. Maybe we’re wrong about the empirics, but I don’t
think we can exclude the possibility that more damage will be done to weak brands
that can’t continue to command a price premium. For one thing, Amazon is not
free riding on the advertising of these producers, because there isn’t any off
Amazon; most of them aren’t like Head & Shoulders, which can advertise and sustain
its brand despite the house brands. I’m not convinced that this is a
distinction that makes a difference, but I’m not convinced it doesn’t.
A: two buckets—small
and medium companies may be different. Batteries often comes up.
Sharon Sandeen:
Trade secrecy background—these bills have no definition of what nonpublic
information is. Small producers are mad at Amazon and want something done, and
this is something, but it may not address what is really going on. Amazon may
also be able to redefine information by contract.
Q: the complaint is
that we don’t have patents or trade secrets, and we don’t yet have a brand
[secondary meaning in the making!] and so Amazon swoops in. One question is
whether that’s what Amazon is doing—appropriating innovative products that aren’t
protected by IP—or whether they’re making batteries and towels, which I would
care less about.
A: it’s popular
goods—not clear about size. But Wal-Mart does the same thing!
Lunney: Generic
house brand just creates price discrimination where otherwise there would be a
[tiny little] monopoly; the parties can split the resulting surplus as they see
fit.
Hughes: Wal-Mart has
been accused of the exact same behavior [of getting into the OEM space and
demanding supply at lower prices] [Lunney: that’s where Wal-Mart v. Samara came
from!]
No comments:
Post a Comment