Panel I: Community Structure and Women’s Leadership in Traditional
Cultural Production
Moderator – Margaret Chon, Seattle University School of Law
Helen Chuma Okoro, Nigerian Institute of Advanced Legal
Studies (and CC Nigeria), Traditional Knowledge, Intellectual Property
Protection, and Matriarchal Dominance: The Case of Traditional Textiles in
South Western Nigeria
Research looked at how to use communal TMs to promote
products in Nigeria, esp. textiles. Findings: very difficult to use communal TM
to promote textile sector particularly, because of structural organization of
sector. Characteristics of textiles:
traditional knowledge; intergenerational in nature. Good reputation: markets exist for the fabric
(adire). Method of production is
natural, organic, by hand.
A market leader, matriarchical structure: mother figure,
very influential. How can that relate to
IP? There’s an idea that traditional knowledge is inconsistent with traditional
IP. But traditional textiles are
fundamentally produced for commercial purposes, so the idea of noncommercial TK
is not relevant; the reputation is what needs protecting. Everyone wants to benefit from the
reputation, so there’s lots of imitation.
Traditional textiles are more expensive to produce; have difficulty
competing with copies/synthetic imitations.
Many families therefore may abandon the production. Need incentive to continue in trade, and IP
could provide that. They understand they
do have some kind of property/right, though they don’t call it IP. They do
share designs, but against outsiders they won’t share. Maternal line transmits
the knowledge.
Small, fragmented industry of producers. Traditional model: result is lots of
competition. Communal methods can work
better—protect designs individually by copyright, individual TM, but lack
enforcement capacity. Nigerian TM act dates from 1965, substandard. Protection
for certification marks but not GIs.
Market mother may be able to provide the necessary structure
to make sure standards are maintained, work hand in hand with standard organization
for certification marks. If that works,
can be transplanted to other sectors.
Lorraine Aragon, University of North Carolina, Cut From the
Same Cloth? Reimagining Copyright’s Relationship with TCEs and Gender in
Indonesia
Between 2003-2010, weaver argued w/district headman about
his plan to © a textile design. Nela’s argument wasn’t technical/legal but
about needs & customs of women.
Widely shared traditions exist across Indonesia; she was defending what
women of the region (not the nation, a recent invention) customarily do—share designs/knowledge. District head predicted econ. benefits to
recently created district; drawing on recently enacted law saying state holds ©
over folklore and people’s cultural products—district’s procedures could be “cut
from the same cloth” as national law.
Offers ways to rethink authorship and property models in
light of gender, in a nonwestern context.
Textiles: how do the weavers view claims over their work? In
Indonesia, this is women’s gendered domain (also pottery); where other TCEs are
more male-controlled. Convergence of IP
and cultural property (CP) models in developing nations—discussed as
provincialization of IP (though all IP can be discussed as
provincialization). Other literature
calls it indigenization of IP. But that doesn’t work for Indonesia; may not
work anywhere that lacks indigenous group membership/enrolled tribes/clear
lines of authority/a state eager to appease indigenous groups. There’s no legal
category of indigenous people in Indonesia, but over 300 ethnic groups.
Reverse anthropology: look at things w/logic of local people. Materiality studies: the spirit/nature/agency
of possessions.
These textiles are handmade, used for ritual
purposes/exchanges; regional market, sometimes internal or external. Internal
market is shared and guarded, somewhat separate from external markets. Index
ancestry & community status; you wouldn’t ordinarily want to make a design
from another group. Some dyes take years
to make. Producers describe themselves
as conduits; say they learn the most complex, dangerous designs in dreams. (Conduit
description is not limited to women—male producers in male genres say the same
thing.) Splitting agency outside the self; carrying on traditions. They do make
claims for themselves, but not ownership or origination claims even though they
might be adding creativity the west would consider copyrightable.
Convergence of IP and CP in Indonesia and several other
places. Variable dynamics of this convergence often go unrecognized. Domestic concerns change response to
TRIPs. Settler states: North America,
Australia, New Zealand—different process than in postcolonial states. Settler states: indigenous groups can advance
political goals through IP claims.
Postcolonial: individual producers have weak status—CP promises the
actual producers very little, even as others get excited about it. Idea of culture as property is not of
interest to producers, because both IP and CP deny their distributive
practices/informal management of system.
Indonesian law: state has © in folklore and people’s cultural
products owned in common; includes stories, dances, clothes, sculptures,
handicrafts, jewelry, traditional weavings, etc. with no time limits on
folklore protection—very big state claim.
The design is not unfamiliar in Indonesia: echoes postcolonial eminent
domain land law. In history of SE Asia, rulers’ interest was never
land/ownership—there was plenty of land. Wanted to control labor. Only when Europeans came in did they look to control land as
property. The idea of private property
is crosscultural—legacy of Dutch control.
Indonesia’s government controls oil; rainforests are being cut down;
wants to diversify its resources = shift to CP.
Property law is there to remedy waste: idea is that if it’s not owned it’s
not being well used—lawyers felt that Indonesians too freely and naively gave
away cultural resources to outsiders, so state has to do it for them.
Repercussions of law: allegations against Malaysia for
cultural theft of batik, beef curry, dances, etc. Accused Robert Wilson of appropriating
a Bugis myth for int’l production of I La Galigo, 2004-2005—he asked for local
permission but state said that wasn’t enough. Pursued w/tremendous passion b/c
IP doesn’t offer them much in conventional form.
District leaders then sought to © elements of “their” local
culture. Flores example on which paper is based is outstanding because there
were no “foreign” cultural thieves at issue. District had been formed from
other districts; district head got the idea that he could © the “chicken
eye” design and collect royalties from weavers who were now outside the
district.
Indonesia long defined geographic-political units according to
ethnicity and TCEs, part of the nation-building project. In reality, people and
TCEs move fluidly across these boundaries.
Weavers said: our ancestors didn’t live only in this new
district; techniques are transferred through marriage and migration. We all
come “from one bamboo clump.” © will
kill the small women entrepreneur—there are so few economic opportunities for
women without capital here, but if some women own certain motifs, they lose
that.
Other women: customary law is weightier and more accepted
than state law. © in state was a solution looking for a problem. The language
of the © law is not intrinsically gendered; makes all producers of TCE
childlike wards of the state.
Can IP provincialization be done in a socially progressive
way that helps indigenous groups? It
doesn’t work as formulated in Indonesia. Could positive law support women’s
customary authority over TCE production?
Unless it does, we can expect them to walk away from it as much as they
can.
Chon: Three major themes: (1) diversity, (2) hybridity, (3)
pluralism. Take us away from the
metaphor of war we’ve worked with in the © field for so long. Oppositional relation between free
expression/exclusive rights—very tired as a metaphor. Hybridity, heterogeneity,
multiplicity instead—but conflict and tension are still inherent in those
relations. This isn’t shiny new happy world, but instead we have many things to
figure out.
Okoro’s matriarchal figure: variations/nuances on this
figure. Existence of multiple markets:
not just global postindustrial mass markets. We need to be more like
antitrust/competition lawyers in looking at the market at issue and its
particular needs. Also: difference in
power structures and leadership. In
Nigeria, power shifts to women in ways that the typical IP model doesn’t
recognize.
Hybridity: both papers talk about TK or CP as it
intersects/hybridizes with formal IP categories, particularly TM and ©, and how
that affects traditional cultures: Okoro is a more positive story, Aragon more
negative. Okoro = fill the needs of a high-end market if it can be connected to
that market. What could be the
incentives to allow traditional weavers to continue work? She identifies certification
mark; what really jumped out in paper is the idea that these textile production
units are family based—going to biological daughters rather than daughters in
law. Deeper commitment, as a result, to the production unit than in a typical
business unit, which we might want to protect.
Can this deep commitment be translated to a highly decentralized, global
market. But one challenge is there’s no
enforcement capacity for small local entrepreneurs and little capacity in the
IP enforcement system period.
Final challenge: how do you signal the qualities—high quality,
handmade, organic, credence attributes—with a relatively shallow right, TM?
Aragon: (1) Social norms, or IP without IP. (2) Second enclosure movement: eminent domain
laws have an analogue in use of © for TCE.
Jamie Boyle has identified this dynamic in West. (3) Facially neutral laws with differential
impacts, as in this case study.
Aragon offers a solution from the people: look at what they’re
doing creatively and think about how to address that production model. Indigenization model doesn’t work in the
context of Indonesia, v. New Zealand with a vocal minority community and a
state eager to appease that community’s legal interests. That goes to
hybridity: local circumstances may be very different from dominant models. Also: these textiles are means of reflecting
and indexing one’s place in the world: how do we hang on to the local identity
in a globalized, marketized world? Use of IP to assert national sovereign
power, vs. Malaysia for example; used as a way for Indonesia to assert its
muscle in the world. How does that work
versus industrialized countries that might appropriate and monetize—Robert
Wilson? Power dynamic of Western
grabbing & not sharing benefits.
Finally, Q posed is whether and how IP can accommodate
communal, local practices. State-owned model
Aragon gave is is clearly not the ideal model, but what is the alternative?
Betsy Rosenblatt: she saw distinctions between ingroup and
outgroup dominating, and Qs of how we define the ingroup. The ingroup in both
cases seemed perfectly capable of governing itself—Q is how they protect selves
from intrusion/appropriation by some outside group, whether industrial copiers
or the state. But Indonesian state saw the ingroup as the whole state, and
wanted to protect against other states.
Okoro: the ingroup isn’t working correctly in Nigeria now
because it’s very hard to protect from outsiders/globalization. Need to go beyond the ingroup model, and IP/TM
is a way to do that.
Aragon: some communities are being flooded w/cheap Chinese
(or Indonesian) knockoffs. Bali deals w/it by info: trying to educate the
tourist about machine/chemical production v. the real thing used in rituals
w/2-year dye made from plants. There are
market conditions where people go to the cheap version b/c that’s what they can
afford. SE Asians in general think the gov’t isn’t helping them with import
issues/trade issues; they don’t specifically care about IP but about local
support/trade laws.
Jessica Silbey: Nigeria—concerns over integrity and misuse.
What counts as misuse? Just copying or a
particular use?
Aruna Ranganathan has been doing ethnographies in India
of local craftmakers—experiments to figure out how they market their work
differently. They will sell their work for less to people who appreciate
authenticity; charge more for people who seem not to care whether it’s an
imitation. Using market segmentation to preserve status, but in the reverse of
what we’d normally see. Shows what people care about in different communities
re: how their work is exchanged and experienced. Seen anything like that kind
of price discrimination used to preserve status, identity, or value?
Okoro: Economic advantage is the primary concern. There are
some textiles with symbolic meaning, but that is not as important here. Profit means that misuse is knockoff/passing
off.
Aragon: price discrimination goes on all the time in
Indonesian markets, but it’s more what we expect—foreigners/nonrelatives get
charged more. May make indigenous
designs with cheap dyes so that local people could afford them. Indonesians wanted to control their own
designs; didn’t care what foreigners did and kept their productions separate;
misuse was generally not of great concern, with a few exceptions.
Irene Calboli: What do traditional people want? Everything:
tradition, control, market access, the ability to set prices—they want what
Westerners want; they want respect for their IP but they don’t care about
knocking off TMs from the west. They see
the value of the model, but understand that w/in the bigger community they have
to play a different game. How IP can
help is difficult—GIs are ways to guarantee geographical region origin, with
variation. If the fake Louis Vuitton
helps sell the real ones, the Pier One knockoff may help sell the authentic
versions—Pier One is often the first access.
Add to this the problem of corrupt governments. Also the role of UNESCO certification—batik has
this certification; tangible and intangible IP are eligible, and gives some
legitimacy.
Aragon: that’s why Indonesia says UNESCO gave them the
copyright and Malaysia can’t do it.
(Even though Calboli points out that is not what UNESCO did.)
Bali is really different from the rest of the country:
commodified genre may worry about knockoffs; others say they want more gov’t
support for things that are disappearing, but they don’t want access to law
because they know that law doesn’t function for them—not looking to sue (or be
sued). Gov’t level and local producer
level must be distinguished; semi- or partially-commodified markets either at
the regional or int’l level. GIs might be something to think about, but not
what they’re thinking about.
Okoro: Agrees they want everything, but textile producers
want more economic advantage primarily. Just like every creator! Dignity to some extent, but at this point
they’re more worried about economic prospects.
Peter Jaszi: To what extent do the modes of regulation
discussed interplay with the imperative for preserving space for dynamism in
traditional culture?
Aragon: Copyright doesn’t seem to be the right measure. Registered designs were ancient but being
claimed by corps/big families. I would look for something grassroots, which isn’t
there yet.
Okoro: the TM model would allow evolution w/in a controlled
environment rather than being overly influenced by economic interests from
outside. Just trying to meet demand from outside kills authenticity, but
creating incentives to maintain traditional quality allows a different basis
for competition.
Jaszi: discusses producers’ difficulty negotiating “living
wage” price from Pier One—a problem not particularly susceptible to IP, but
perhaps to consumer information and some militancy by well-meaning consumers.
Even if Pier One is an entry point, right now those outlets are killing rather
than sustaining the communities whose goods are being exported.
Chon: a problem of information flow rather than IP per se.
No comments:
Post a Comment