Oral argument transcript here:
Most of the questions seemed to me more favorable to Static Control, though
Kennedy said almost nothing.
Steven B. Loy - Stoll Keenon Ogden PLLC, representing
Lexmark
Lexmark makes printers and cartridges: position is that
primary competitors are HP etc. Aftermarket developed for depleted cartridges,
remanufactured/refilled with toner.
Lexmark does that too. Static
Control provides components to remanufacturers.
This case involved every potential IP claim: patent, patent misuse,
antitrust, copyright. Today was Lanham
Act day: Lexmark allegedly made actionable statements: (1) told customers that
refilling cartridges would infringe Lexmark’s rights; (2) told remanufacturers
that refilling cartridges would infringe Lexmark’s rights and that using Static
Control’s products would infringe.
First, Second, and Sixth Circuit used reasonable interest
test for standing; categorical rule requiring competition in 7th, 9th,
and 10th; AGC antitrust test, 3d Cir., 5th, 11th. They advocated for AGC.
Seth Greenstein - Constantine Cannon LLC, representing
Static Control Components, Inc.
Lexmark has a razors/razorblade model, making money off of
supplies instead of printers. Interested
in finding different ways to restrict sources of cartridges for
remanufacturers. Following patent exhaustion cases, Lexmark adopted “prebate”—advance
discount on price, with a label with an alleged patent license/restriction
saying that Lexmark could remanufacture it.
Lexmark adopted a technology—a chip with software that talked to
printer—so that as the cartridge was used, the printer wrote data onto the
chip. If remanufactured cartridge showed up with chip, printer would stop
working. Static Control’s chips mimicked
Lexmark’s, allowing remanufactured cartridges to work.
Initial lawsuit: copyright infringement/DMCA
violations. Preliminary injunction
against Static Control was reversed in 2004.
Also patent issues. Static
Control counterclaimed for state and federal false advertising/antitrust
claims. Static Control didn’t have
antitrust standing federally, per 6th Cir.
Rebecca Tushnet - Georgetown University Law Center,
representing amicus curiae, Law Professors
Why should people who are primarily interested in TM
care? Because the statutory language is
the same/hard to distinguish. Historical
note: “unfair competition requires competition” and its disappearance from the
case law in trademark. Does trademark
have a fundamentally different basis than false advertising law? The statutory text is virtually identical,
especially as to the relevant concepts.
Lurking issues: “commercial advertising or promotion” and its
relationship to the standing arguments here.
Marc A. Goldman - Jenner & Block LLP, representing
amicus curiae American Intellectual Property Law Association
AIPLA participates in almost every SCt IP case. Supported a relatively broad test, given a
membership that runs the gamut of positions.
Similar to Law Professors: congressional intent should be the key for
assessing standing. Existing tests are
somewhat divorced from that. Language is very broad in the Lanham Act. Don’t depart without really good reason. At least congressional purpose. Categorical test can’t explain prohibition on
false association claims. AGC sometimes doesn’t even protect direct
competitors. Given that, it’s the wrong test, especially the factors that look
to speculativeness/duplicative potential for damages; antitrust is a very
different kind of law. Lanham Act
provides injunctive relief, not just damages; factors aimed at damages
therefore don’t make sense. Antitrust is
generally designed to protect consumers, while Lanham Act is also designed to
protect competitors—antitrust is happy if someone sues, but Lanham Act
specifically protects competitors who should get to sue.
Mary Massaron Ross - Immediate Past President of DRI - The
Voice of the Defense Bar, representing amicus curiae, DRI
DRI has 22,000 members, representing businesses/individuals
in civil litigation. Experience of
lawyers in trenches. Practical
approach. Categorical test: most
restrictive. We believe a rule-like test
is better in practice. Easier to apply
and outcome is more predictable and avoids ideological divergence. (RT: 9th Circuit experience doesn’t
really bear that out.) Protects against
unfair competition. Narrower standing is
good for federalism concerns. Leave areas
of state tort law unsubsumed into federal statutory scheme, which is a good
thing. Overenforcement of Lanham Act
chills information available in the marketplace. Reasonable interest isn’t enough for
predictability.
Moderated by: Christine Farley - American University
Washington College of Law
Farley: asked lawyers for parties to reflect on amici’s
arguments.
Loy: DRI is closest to right. A number of tests exist; AGC has worked well
for 30 years in antitrust, and 15 years in the 3rd Circuit. The alternative is not to go to a rudderless
test, but a categorical test. Reasonable interest test is no more than Article
III test, and obviously we need more than Article III standing. Specific statute with specific statutory
purpose: AGC test is specific to that.
Reasonable interest test couldn’t be taken at its word—added components
to it that weren’t part of the test: purpose is to protect against unfair
competition, but consumers universally don’t have standing. The 2d Circuit adds a heightened showing if
plaintiff is noncompetitor; we don’t know what that heightened showing is, but
that’s beyond the test itself. Zone of
interest/reasonable interest requires more work, and AGC has already provided a
framework, apart from determining any particular set of facts.
Greenstein: practicing lawyers who specialized in Lanham Act
lined up largely to support reasonable interest/commercial interest: false
advertising distorts the marketplace, and the statute decided that private
parties should vindicate that right.
Trends exist in case law applying the reasonable interest test that
provide useful lessons: consumers don’t have standing, competitors do, and
others with strong commercial interests can—not adding components, just
jurisprudential development. Unfair competition as actual competition between
parties: unfair competition is a rubric applied to various things, not just
direct competition. The language of the
statute is “any person,” and Congress knows how to require competition if it
wants to; it’s done so in other statutes. RT: on predictability of categorical
test: 9th Circuit experience doesn’t really bear that out. Risk of overenforcement:
direct competitors are the ones most likely to make chilling claims, because
they have the most anticompetitive motives; if you’re concerned about
overenforcement the standing test is the wrong place to look. Claims that AGC is working well: Except where
it hasn’t worked well at all, as I’ve detailed elsewhere (in the brief
and Running the Gamut). AGC circuits are
divided for example on how to evaluate duplicativeness of damages, and they
deny standing to direct competitors. 2d Circuit is at least as active as the
3d, and no disaster/rudderlessness. I’d
have a harder time counseling someone in the 5th/11th
circuits about the law than the 2d.
Goldman: letting “any person” have standing would also be
predictable. In a world where we’re departing from that, we should consider
congressional purposes. 2d Circuit has
focused on congressional intent, similar to the zone of interest tests as
characterized by respondents. AGC’s
rudder doesn’t come from any source within the statute and produces wrong
results.
Ross: Breyer asked whether consumers should be able to bring
suit; should every other fast food restaurant be able to sue McDonald’s? What
about the local health food burger joint?
(Wouldn’t they have standing under the categorical test? If not, what’s so categorical?) There’s a wide universe of potential suits
and her sense of Justices’ questions was that it was untenable to let everyone
in the universe, including consumers, sue; the question then is what’s the test
to differentiate those who can sue from those who can’t. Using malleable words
like reasonable works well in fact-based tests but that’s not good for a
consistent legal determination made to treat similar cases similarly. Static Control was urging a zone of interest
test—even more fluid than many oral arguments in terms of options available to
the Court. Justices might be inclined to
develop their own test as opposed to latching on to any one articulated below.
Farley: talk about the argument.
Loy: awe-inspiring. No substitute for preparation for
answering questions. The Justices are
debating the issues and you’re there with them.
Greenstein: Surprising that this was the issue in this
long-running case that got to the SCt, as opposed to the also interesting
DMCA/patent issues. Static Control
argued for a fourth test, the test the Court applies more generally to standing
where there’s no specific common law background or statutory standard—zone of
interests; see who’s arguably within the zone intended to be protected by
Congress. The SCt has the most experience with this, applying it in a number of
settings from its birth under the Administrative Procedure Act. Seemed logical for Lanham Act and potentially
any statutory scheme. Wide-ranging conversation about different tests. There
were questions about AGC’s flaws and also about the reasonable interest
test. Justice Kagan wanted to know why
we didn’t just look at the statute.
Justice Scalia asked what the point of prudential standing was here. Hypotheticals: any test will pose questions
about who’s in and who’s out at the margins.
He thought the court accepted pretty clearly that Static
Control had standing for claims made about Static Control’s products
themselves, given the 1988 amendments.
But when defendant makes statements about its own products it gets more complicated. Then-Judge Alito wrote Conte Bros., which should have the same result under reasonable
interest test—a class of retailers who didn’t market defendants’ products but
claimed injury from statements about defendants’ own products. But retailers could have standing under some
circumstances, he thinks, just as parts suppliers could under some
circumstances. Depends on whether the falsity relates to the part supplier’s
product. Statements about Lexmark’s chip
is within the zone of interests Static Control has, as chip maker, but not
within the zone of interests for the maker of the box that the printer
cartridge comes in.
Goldman: most interesting about argument: there were many
questions about what prudential standing was doing as a concept. Congressional intent as touchstone. There’s a
real possibility that the Court will look at that. How does that play out? They do seem to have various prudential
concerns—they don’t want everybody to be able to sue, especially not
consumers. It’s fairly straightforward
to exclude consumers, he thinks, despite the broad standing provision.
Ross: Justices had this notion about “why do we have the
power to set these limits when Congress has spoken?” Constitutional standing, Article III, is a
set test, and it allows standing more readily at the constitutional level than
at the prudential level. When Congress
uses broad phrases, it’s a signal but there are always plaintiffs who go too
far, and that’s where prudential standing arose from.
RT: you know, why shouldn’t consumers have standing if the statutory
language supports it?
Michael Carroll: when plaintiff falsely advertises about its
own products, who should have standing, according to the various tests? Justice Breyer used a hypo about a claim that
the chocolate used at a particular shop was poisonous. Should the shop have standing?
Loy: district courts will have to apply test to given set of
facts. AGC also supports standing for
false endorsement cases. Under
reasonable interest test consumers could
have standing!
Greenstein: ducking the hypothetical shows the flaws in
AGC/categorical tests. One ice cream
maker saying a store’s sauce was poisonous—the entity attacked would lack
standing even though it’s the most directly harmed. Even under AGC they should
get standing when there’s a direct statement maligning their products.
RT: hypos about disparagement don’t really get to the “false
advertising about one’s own products” issue.
Congressional purpose: protect consumers and commercial entities; those two aims don’t have to compete.
Goldman: direct competitors have the most plausible story
about how false advertising about one’s own products harms the competitor;
multiple people might also be harmed, and further down the line can they sue?
These are harder questions even as a matter of background common law; there’s
some point at which proximate cause is lacking but it may be several steps down
the chain. None of the tests have a great way of answering that question in the
abstract.
Ross: rules versus standards scholarship: both have benefits
and costs. How clear you want to be
versus how much you want to take hypos into account. Categorical test has the benefit of focusing
Lanham Act on direct competition, as is the purpose thereof. Sure that leaves some people out, but Lanham
Act is directed at protecting competition against false statements. (Except that “competition” hasn’t meant
direct competition in the rest of the Lanham Act for 60 years. If you give me “unfair competition requires
competition” in trademark, I’ll accept it in false advertising.) State tort causes of action remain available.
No comments:
Post a Comment