Plenary Session: How Do Patents Affect Innovation?
Facilitator: Katherine Strandburg (NYU)
Longer history of empirical work in patent, but still
difficulty answering basic question of effect on innovation. In 1958, economist
Fritz Machlup famously concluded that “none of the empirical evidence at our
disposal” “either confirms or confutes the belief that the patent system has
promoted the progress of the technical arts and the productivity of the
economy.” Are we in a better position
today?
Panelists: Heidi Williams (MIT Dep’t of Economics)
Topic: Measuring the Effects of Patents on Downstream
Innovation, Commenting on: Alberto Galasso & Mark Schankerman, Patents
and Cumulative Innovation: Causal Evidence from the Courts (2013)
How to patents on existing tech affect follow-on
innovation? Two key challenges have
hindered prior work: how can we construct an appropriate counterfactual? Can’t randomize patents for some tech and not
others. Selection bias is a problem.
Insight: lever CAFC judge assignment for variation in active patents;
this experiment holds disclosure constant.
Second challenge: measurement. What paper trail can measure follow-on
innovation? Patent citations can’t be
used to track innovation on tech that doesn’t receive patents. Using patent invalidations makes citations a
feasible outcome.
Does invalidation change investment in follow-on
innovation? No estimated effect on
pharma cases, but Williams suggests that awareness of such cases and their
likely outcome means that invalidation proceedings’ likelihood are already
incorporated into investment decisions.
Economists have looked carefully at citations: hybrid corn
patents, where yield of corn provides some measure of patent value. What are the citations measuring? Inventors and
examiners cite a core set of patents that establish patentable subject matter (PSM)
in an area—citations establish many things.
Case could be cited more/less because it’s being used to define PSM—so that
might not provide a measure of follow-on innovation.
Authors are aware of this, but note the difficulty of
finding a measure of innovation—tried to collect non-citation measures of
follow-on innovation: clinical trials for pharma—when a patent is invalidated,
do you see more clinical trials on that active ingredient? Medical device registrations: if invalidated,
do you see more medical devices measured by FDA registrations? Consistently w/citation results, they don’t
see impact on clinical trials (though since these cases involve ANDAs there
might not be new information revealed anyway); medical device data are more
nuanced—new devices/generic versions of existing devices: when there’s an
invalidation, you get more generic device registrations—substantially
equivalent to product whose patent is invalidated. Not sure that this measures follow-on
innovation; these don’t require licenses and may just reflect changes in
competition.
Excellent empirical work; leaves open questions.
Stefan Bechtold (ETH Zurich)
Topic: The Effects of Patents on Scientific Research, Commenting
on: Bhaven Sampat & Heidi L. Williams, How Do Patents Affect Follow-On
Innovation? Evidence from the Human Genome
Try to identify variable correlated w/ explanatory variable
but doesn’t suffer from causality/endogeneity problems of explanatory
variable. Existing literature: IP rights
without disclosure may reduce follow-on academic research/commercial
development; with disclosure IP rights may reduce downstream innovation in
computers, electronics, medical instruments, but not in drugs, chemicals, or
mechanical technologies. Paper: do
patents in human genes affect follow on innovation as measured by scientific
research and product development?
Look at patent applications, both successful and
unsuccessful. Gene sequences extracted
from patent claims and linked to data on publication citation, clinical trials,
and diagnostic tests. Endogeneity: genes claimed in patent applications may
have different characteristics than genes are never claimed; inventors may file
for more valuable technologies. Look
then at successful v. unsuccessful applicants, as well as examiner variance. Random variation? In fact assignment isn’t
random, but within art units it’s random; key question is whether successful
and unsuccessful applications are similar at the time of application. Use leniency of individual patent examiner.
In general, no effect of gene patents on follow-on
innovation. No decline or increase in
follow-on publications and clinical trials.
What’s the relevance of the economist v. legal
scholars? Lawyers know institutional
details so they can figure out what might be causal.
Michael Meurer (Boston University)
Topic: Non-Patent Measures of Innovation, Commenting on:
Petra Moser, Patents and
Innovation: Evidence from Economic History, 27 J. Econ. Persp. 23 (2013)
Douglas North: emphasized secure property rights, rule of
law for role in innovation in Industrial Revolution. Skeptics: with exception
of James Watt, few prominent innovators profited from patents or even got them. Aggregate data on growth and availability of
IP rights: methods of measuring patent strength are fairly crude, and there are
problems of endogeneity: which came first—innovation or strong patent rights?
Harmonization has been effective today: Chinese patent
system differs very little from American system in relevant ways—that gives an
advantage to 19th c patent data where there’s a large amount of
credibly exogenous variation in patent law; mostly domestic patenting prior to
Paris Convention.
Besides aggregate data, there are case studies. Much work on collective invention/knowledge
sharing in blast furnaces, high pressure steam engines, weaving machinery
(learning by doing): ways to appropriate value by patents, trade secrets, or
some form of open sharing—when it’s not necessary to get a patent to drive
innovation and invention. Sewing machine,
for example, was recombinant technology drawing on lots of previous innovations
spread out over time. Research: patent
pool seemed to decrease innovation; pool members seemed to innovate less.
Evidence of maximum stitch rate: growing before pool, leveled out during pool,
grew again after pool. No pool in England; controlling for variations across
inventions, found significant dampening of R&D especially by US pool
members. Previous economists looking at patent pools didn’t pay much attention
to outsiders, but they played a big role—effective threats of patent litigation
from pool pushed them to invent around. Is that normatively desirable? Wasteful duplication or better innovation? Others
have explored patent patents, compulsory licenses, periodic table.
Comparability: Economists can be informed about
institutional details with case studies that are contemporaneous; harder when
your case studies are 150 years old. Archival research is also necessary.
Petra Moser (Stanford Dep’t of Economics)
Topic: Measuring the Effects of Patents on Private
Incentives, Commenting on: James Bessen et al., The Costs and
Benefits of United States Patents (2014)
Estimating private costs and benefits of US patents owned by
publicly held firms. Event study approach to estimated losses suffered by
alleged infringers 1984-2009; authors use market value regressions to estimate
value of patent rents for publicly traded US firms. Findings: Total private
costs exceed private benefits; excess costs increase over time surege in
lawsuits (NPE, computers/communications patents, software and telecom); growth
in private costs outstrips growth in lawsuits (lawsuits cost increases over
time).
Lower bound estimates of costs according to paper: but that’s
not precise enough for Moser—study measures effect of threat of filing law
suit, but what happens when a firm wins or loses a lawsuit or unexpectedly has
to defend? Innovation incentives: even
if costs outweigh rents, if rents are given to those who don’t bear the costs,
then innovation incentives could still be huge.
Suggests looking at individual cases rather than aggregate evidence.
Differences across countries: use EPO patents to look at how
differences in patent systems influence private costs and benefits. Considering
US patent only: upper bound rent of $517,000 per patent 1979-2002, adding EPO
patents gets you to $351,000 per patent.
No comments:
Post a Comment