Michael Burstein, The Law of the Direction of Innovation
Foundational texts: NBER Rate and Direction of Inventive
Activity, and revisited. But we need to ask: what innovation should we
prioritize? What innovation, by whom, and for whom? These are contestable
subjects of political choice. Health law scholars have started to ask why so
many me too drugs instead of novel therapeutics; trying to generalize from
these questions.
Positing two axioms representing conventional wisdom in law
& business: (1) entrepreneurial activity, mediated by price signals and
supplemented by exclusive rights, is the best way to establish the direction of
innovation. (2) private ordering of innovation policy takes place largely in
the absence of legal structure; law’s role is only to ensure that IP
facilitates adequate price signaling.
This is wrong in a few ways. Startups direct innovative
efforts towards funders’ interests—structured by VC incentives. Incumbent firms
are influenced by corporate rules. Covenants not to compete matters. That’s all
not just price. Even if was just price, IP doesn’t mediate price in a vacuum;
IP makes choices. Market demand also doesn’t equal social demand/value of
innovation. Gov’t funding remains an important tool of innovation policy.
How do we get an innovation ecosystem w/striking disparities
in investment/development of tech that we see today? VC investment is mostly in
IT and consumer-oriented stuff. Silicon Valley has become optimized to produce
those kinds of innovations. Crypto, but not encryption from same underlying
tech base. Crypto has low capital requirements, low barriers to entry.
Encryption is deep tech, w/long and uncertain regulatory cycle/demand, but
potentially much greater social value.
We’ve had different innovation systems over time—Bell Labs,
corporate R&D.
One goal: challenge notion that innovation is part of market
alone and not part of legal choice.
Gaps in literature to fill: economic literature has some
useful modeling, but doesn’t explain mechanisms by which economic incentives
actually arise. Innovation ecosystems may be described, but each part of
ecosystem is molded by various laws, private law and public law. In law, we tend
not to see the ecosystem as deserving of integrated study—we tend to atomize
each piece.
Law influences direction by structuring relationships among
firms, individuals, and markets (VC contracts are an example: generally
applicable law rather than innovation specific); by delineating entitlements
(creation/enforcement of legal rights or creating space for nonmarket
innovation); creating or limiting markets—shaping demand (export controls that
limit the addressable market for certain tech); subsidizing investments,
generally through gov’t spending or the equivalent (gov’t grants).
Harder cases: corporate governance—that shapes both
individual firms/people as well as markets as a whole. R&D tax credits; gov’t
procurement—both a subsidy and market-making. Regulation—can prohibit and can
structure what people can do, and direction of innovation responds in kind. IP
may operate across modes. Delineating entitlements and subsidizing investments
by overcoming public goods problems, but also shapes market, e.g. by
identifying what’s protectable and unprotectable and by shaping licensing law.
Sapna Kumar: how does the model handle goods that more
closely resemble public goods than private goods, like new antibiotics and
vaccines for infectious diseases less common in the US now (but might be in the
future). Infrastructural goods might be different.
A: the market paradigm tells us the underproduction problem
is bigger with such goods, so it wouldn’t surprise him if things like
regulation/gov’t procurement play a bigger role there.
Rosenblatt: people are uncomfortable with value judgments:
which technologies are value-promoting and which aren’t.
Kumar, Scientiļ¬c and Technical Expertise after Loper Bright
Her impression: majority fundamentally misunderstood
intertwining of sci/tech expertise w/statutory interpretation. Lessons we can learn
from patent litigation about how judges acquire needed knowledge about technical
issues. Proposal: funding neutral experts for appellate courts for complex
administrative law cases.
Loper Bright: Judges must independently interpret statutes. Judges
must exercise independent judgment when they interpret ambiguous statutes;
adopted very narrow version of Skidmore deference—can’t defer to agencies but
can look for persuasiveness, doesn’t seem different from being persuaded by a
party or amicus. Claimed holding based on APA, but framed decision w/in Art.
III arguments—invoked Marbury twice.
Many prominent scholars claim lots of deference is left, but
her own view is that lots has changed. Courts are forbidden from deferring. LB
might exacerbate politicization for judges. Some judges may try to improperly
defer. But what about judges who try to faithfully follow LB—what is a
deference-free system of interpretation?
Patent has some lessons! District judges struggle to
understand complex sci/tech, which contributes to patent cases being
time-consuming. They cope by relying heavily on expert tech tutorials,
technically trained clerks, tech-trained magistrate judges, and neutral experts
for complex cases, sometimes special master or technical adviser. How does the
CAFC cope? Expertise of the judges themselves, and technically trained law
clerks.
We don’t have any of that for APA situations. No means for
parties providing tech tutorials; appellate courts have few technically trained
clerks; page limits on briefs and non-tech trained lawyers make it hard for
judges to learn what they need; no means for hiring neutral experts at
appellate level.
Neutral expert proposal has been floating around for a bit:
Breyer & Leventhal, JJ, both proposed. Common in other countries, EU and
England. Best of both worlds—independent judgment of judges & access to
reputable info on sci/tech.
Implementation: Congress could fund it up front (unlikely);
appellate courts could do this on their own and bill parties for cost (is this
allowed?). Experts would explain background sci/tech, not opine in law. Give
teachings in written form, subject to party response. Goal to prevent overreliance
and opacity, while preserving adversarial system. Patent system suggests that
this can work. This isn’t a substitute for Chevron, but it’s something.
RT: Could an appellate ct send to dct for this purpose?
A: would take amending the APA.
Burstein: can appellate courts appoint special masters?
A: seen conflicting things—need more research into their
inherent authority.
Jacob Sherkow: there are original APA actions in the dct—those
could have experts.
Q: generalist judges are always coming into situations they
don’t know anything about—music, reinsurance markets, complex family
situations, how do ski resorts work. That doesn’t mean anything you said is
wrong. But why is science special?
A: dct often plays a filtering role.
Q: problem where you can’t find an expert who isn’t in one
camp or another—an interest in advancing (or not) large hadron collider
projects. Maybe you need to hire 2-3 with different ways of looking at the same
thing.
A: that’s true.
No comments:
Post a Comment