Fourth Session:
Reputation and Policy Take-Aways
Abraham Drassinower:
what does thinking about misalignment tell us how to think about IP? Move from debunking eureka myth to debunking
the myth of progress. Misalignment of IP
with its own justifications, needs of its creators. Whatever IP is, it’s not an
instrument of progress. Realign it with
its own progressive purpose?
Because you’re
talking about misalignment b/t interview data and progress, you’re not talking
about whether progress should be the focus of our attention. Quantity is the wrong metric. Social engineer with balances can’t figure it
out. The concept of value, and circulation
of value, can’t provide sufficient foundation for the specifically legal
concept of IP. Like Holmes in INS v. AP
who tells us that property is a social category. But will qualitative approach answer the question
either? If the problem is indeterminacy, then lived experience may not help
answer the question of value. Then IP
remains unjustified as instrument of progress.
One conclusion:
strong IP/maximalism is not correlated with progress. Correction of mistake: gather more data but
the justificatory mechanism remains collecting data to achieve progress. But it seems at least as plausible to ask
whether your empirical observation that IP doesn’t align with progress doesn’t
mean that IP isn’t an instrument of progress.
Maybe it’s about something else.
Hard to say in the US though.
More subtly: it’s the meaning of progress, rather than the nature of evidence to be deployed, that requires interrogation. But that seems to require not a recalibration of IP but rather a reassessment of what it means to gather data when you’re trying to justify something. It’s very hard to get rid of the incentive story by looking at evidence.
Questions: (1) What
is progress? (2) Is progress the same for all three cardinal branches of IP? (3) How can data collection answer normative/legal
justification questions? Not saying it doesn’t, just saying it’s not
self-evident.
Joe Bauer: Difference
between individual and corporate aims: corporation aims at maximizing rewards.
But corporation is a legal fiction. IP is directed towards wealth for
owners. Are we as a society acting at
our peril if a reduction in those rewards significantly reduces willingness to
invest in IP. (Well, how are the
relative returns?) Also, corporations
aren’t one size fits all—financial rewards may play greater or lesser
role. Significant investment/unclear
payoff may be different: movies; pharmaceuticals.
Should we fine-tune
the rules to differ across types of work, authors, inventors, owners? Should we give more attribution rights, and
if so is the European model appropriate or some American version? Copyright and patent are exclusive; is the
implication of your analysis that compulsory licensing would be better?
Barton Beebe: IP as
enabling rather than incentivizing—a key insight. Creating conditions for play—connection w/Julie
Cohen’s work. How that relates to
process over product: good IP facilitates the process and doesn’t allow
incentivization imperative to destroy facilitation. Facilitation applies to
second-generation artists; importance of derivative works comes out.
Shifting away from
process into trademark law: is trademark law the same as attribution and
reputation? Not quite. Open source
communities is very anti-IP but get very fussy if you don’t honor attribution
rights. Creators (note it’s a charged
term) accept less money if you offer them autonomy and attribution. Unalienated labor can be had more cheaply;
they also want connections with consumers.
Make the market human to them; you can pay them less.
Book reports
overreach; people become aggressive and fussy whereas underenforcement prevails
in the rest of the book. Human
attribution is dangerous in the corporate context—the whole point of TM these
days is not to indicate source but to obscure it—no, this shoe was not made in
the Phillippines by an underpaid child, it was made by Nike. Branding as authenticating source—old strict
source theory of TM law has been replaced by anonymous source rule. Book shows that everyday TM law isn’t about
branding or persuasion but defamation/right of integrity. A name is a creative act (Laura
Heymann).
(1) Star
systems/mere mortals. (2) What about
those who don’t rise to the level of pro paid artist or who give up? Adolescents’ views? (3) Concept of the romantic author and how it
might fit in. Romantic author as solitary voice/artist struggling in face of massification
and speaks ex nihilo, creating something out of nothing. A concept created in response to new material
conditions of industrial production—secularization of Protestant tradition per
Martha Woodmansee. Never actually bought
this as explaining copyright law. We use
the trope of the author creating ex nihilo to justify IP rights—if the author
didn’t create out of a community, then he deserves all this money. Silbey’s book creates image of people opposed
to the market, working for other reasons, in opposition to industrial
capitalism, but is that opposition really as opposed as all that?
Market aspect to
reputation: people who get to construct themselves as playwrights/novelists
while being supported by spouses—if they’re wealthy that’s cool, if not we
judge them horribly.
Mark McKenna: very
few people wanted to talk about reputation here. Hard to figure out what to say. Merges’ reaction: this book fully justifies a
strong attribution right overruling Dastar.
But reputation is used in a number of different senses throughout the book by
interviewees. Some talk about their reputation as scientists/artists—for being
creative/innovative. Others talk about reputation in business world/ability to
get deals done. Then there’s reputation as source. Reductionist move to either talk about TM or
right of attribution. But different uses may have little to do either w/TM or ©. Attribution right would do no work for most
of these reputational issues—the things that bothered artists most were some of
the things they had the least justified claim to control, and giving control over
those things to the artists might well be unconstitutional.
The more you see in
TM law, the more you should worry about a free floating right of attribution.
What counts as a “work” deserving attribution?
A piece? Whatever the author says? Who gets to say who’s a source? Experience w/TM law is not promising.
Why is the impulse
to provide an attribution right to an artist and not to the people who stitch
the shoes, who are also vital to the creation and might care a lot too.
If you were
designing a legal system to deal with all these kinds of reputation, would want
to think more about harm. In some cases the harms might have economic
consequences but in others they might be purely emotional. Under what
circumstances are those harms real? Or are they just idiosyncratic harms to the
author? Might see inverse relationship
between most significant dignitary harm and greatest willingness to provide
rights; thus his deep suspicion of attribution. Reputation is not one thing.
Nicole Garnett: Some people respond to incentives and the Q is
whether they’re producing what we want.
Decide what the “more” is and then investigate how the incentive
works.
Overreach/leakiness—all
about optimal enforcement. Book seems to
give sense that level of enforcement is not optimal, but we never want 100%
enforcement of the law. Fact of exclusion rights enables community; owner can
tolerate intrusion on lawn because that won’t actually dispossess her. What’s optimal level of leakiness? Especially in communities where norms do more
work than law.
Loren: Likes Traffix because court is clear that it’s
concerned with harassment value of IP right: default rules that don’t allow
quick dismissal can harm competitors for lawful behavior. It’s that harassment value that is the
overreach. Twiqbal has helped
dismissal for ridiculous copyright claims.
What’s the harassment suit value of an attribution claim? That’s what
makes her nervous.
Garnett: rights
always raise possibility of harassment suits. Is it particularly bad here?
McKenna: tied to the
remedy. If there were statutory damages available there’d be nuisance value to
suits.
Loren: harassment
value used to be much higher because of possibility of preliminary injunction.
Golden: making
inequalities worse through just providing attribution?
RT: Carol Rose:
rights are means of communicating. If
they aren’t clear or are misunderstood, trouble can arise. Or different
communities w/different norms intersect and clash.
Silbey: could be
very hard to understand what interviewees meant by reputation. It’s a category
that didn’t make sense as a whole. [RT:
could see it as a cluster of concepts/prototypes.] Point about blowback of
attribution right—agrees with McKenna’s assessment.
Said:
underenforcement—we have no duty to police ©.
Silbey: may have given
them the category by asking; there are still multiple issues w/ meaning.
Kelly: culture and
habits; mixed motivation could be consistent w/law and econ, but here’s one
place where assumptions miss the boat by starting w/individual instead of more
social view of the person, in context/social setting.
Loren: © and patent
as driving different types of innovation than trade secrets, live performance,
etc. As long as there’s sufficient respect for the distribution models chosen,
it can work. Price discrimination/arbitrage: if it avoids a chosen distribution
model then maybe it’s not justified.
Drassinower: legal
construct of moral rights limits their scope: not a general defamation
protection. Did interviewees have a
defined sense of what a reputation was?
Beebe: we didn’t
talk much about the chapter on lawyers.
Lawyers aren’t the talent; they’re a cost center, as one interviewee
says. Was there a class division?
Silbey: trying to be
helpful to people who don’t think they need you but they do.
Schwartz: litigators
are problem solvers—may be seen differently than transactional lawyers.
Silbey: necessary
evil (litigators). In-house tended to be more transactional, but many had moved
between roles over time, except for patent specialists who only drafted patents
or did audits. Even young ones generally
had varied experience.
Golden: reputation
among informed peers/reputation among consuming public might differ. Lawyers drafting patents have to avoid becoming
inventors themselves. Lawyers can also
have involvement w/designing around.
DiCola: one bit in the
lawyer chapter that he really liked was a music agent convincing an artist to
take the money for a 30-second spot.
That’s a representative story—there was a moment when VW started
licensing indie rock and it became ok because VW was cool; shift from “don’t
sell out” to “I need the money.”
Cohen: IP lawyers
have a choice: discipline the talent by normalizing output that can be
monetized, or they’re mediating between creators and firms, taking into account
that firm’s demands can’t just be ignored but that talent has demands as
well. The people whose stories seem
happy are those who are mediating. When
we teach IP, are we teaching a hermetically sealed causality story or teaching
the need to mediate? We can do the
latter.
Professional
responsibility questions: the Model Rules are litigation focused; don’t get at
this delicate negotiation at all.
Institution-building as a goal.
Contrast: MERS and professional responsibility—people are going in to
foreclose with no evidence, and now it’s a professional responsibility issue at
the individual foreclosure level. But
nobody in power is saying that Covington did this incredibly unethical thing by
building this powerful institution, MERS, at the behest of the top banks, even
when it was absolutely foreseeable from day 1 that it would screw up the real
property system. Lawyers build stuff:
they built Spotify; they built Aereo. That’s a kind of mediation too.
Golden: see constant
demand by clients for noninfringement/invalidity opinions in patent; some
lawyers seem willing to provide those.
You might orally communicate your opinion if it’s unfavorable; they
might shop around. That’s a product that
comes from the lawyers, though of course it’s to overcome a problem created by
lawyers elsewhere.
No comments:
Post a Comment