Plenary Session
Making Copyright Work for Creative Upstarts
Sean Pager
Imagine you’re a singer in a rock band, and hear your song
used unauthorized for a car commercial. You call and they brush you off. You can’t afford a lawyer, and costs of
litigating in federal court could dwarf any license fee you might recover. If
you never registered you have no eligibility for statutory damages and
attorneys’ fees. You quit and go to law school.
Our standard theory of copyright is that we give rights to
incentivize creation, but rights aren’t self executing. Without capacity to use
them, they’re not useful. Copyright might not be doing the work it’s supposed
to. Our system assumes sophistication—simple
Qs often have convoluted answers, and that’s just the formal law, not the
institutions that implement them and have complexities of their own. Registration alone; signing up for ASCAP/BMI;
SoundExchange; Google’s Content ID—a lot of registries to keep track of.
Broader Q: who is our © system for? 19th c. might have been reasonable
to assume that © users were capital-intensive endeavors. What to do now that creation doesn’t look
like that? Mobile app designers, indie
filmmakers, graphic artists—how are they doing in the © system?
What would an upstart-friendly system look like? Increasing legal certainty—more safe harbors
and bright line rules. Small claims
process—better if mandatory. Enhanced
damages tied to registration should be reconsidered. $35-55 to register is a lot for a graphic
artist. Tech can be used—interoperability,
common-sense standards to allow one-stop registration; streamlined online
licensing, as w/UK’s Copyright Hub targeted at low-value works to be licensed
efficiently using automated mechanisms. Or
expert systems automated to give advice—compare increased ease of tax now that
we have TurboTax—similar system for copyright users. (Note that TurboTax
has engaged in a lot of funky behavior to prevent tax simplification—a Copyright
Hub might do the same, especially if it were a private, profit-seeking
organization.)
Menell: Creative upstarts should be able to find works/use
Content ID to quickly ID ownership, and on backend streamlining system would be
good, but more worried about front end of enabling people to find and
navigate. If they’re not willing to pay
$35 to register, should we give them such strong protections for how their
works float in the ether.
A: maybe find way to register high volume of works at once.
Lemley: useful points about small creators. Q is what are we
to make of the fact that we are nonetheless seeing an unprecedented wave of
such creators. We have more video, music, books than ever before, most coming
from people outside the © industries. What does that mean? They don’t seem to
be quitting and going to law school, whether they should or not.
A: Commercialization—amateurs may create a lot, but don’t
invest as much. Making a full length feature film takes resources, while you
can write a book on your own. iPhone
filmmakers are limited in what they can do, so we need to find a way to make
film pay.
Lemley: sounds like there’s sorting between upstarts and
more commercially oriented folks, but those may be more attuned to © system as
already exists.
(I agree w/Lemley.
W/r/t the opening story: If most commercializers behave most of the
time, though, is that so much worse than other elements of starting your own
business? There is plagiarism of works
on Amazon’s self-publishing, but there’s also persistence. Overconfidence about success is often
important in incentivizing creation/starting a business/etc. Is © any different
than the other rules that aren’t necessarily enforced (e.g., wage theft)?)
A: there’s a spectrum. Better access to © system may enable
you to negotiate better terms.
Q: valid points about accessibility. Is enforcement
necessarily the issue? Even in perfect enforcement world, would their captured
revenue stream allow people to avoid going to law school? It could just be that people are flocking to
fewer and fewer items—how big is the pie?
A: demand is partly influenced by supply. Change the system to make it easier for
independents to have access—not just ©--people might embrace more products, not
just blockbusters.
Q: so the issue is that people aren’t entering the market
who otherwise would? Or that they’re entering without being able to recoup
value?
A: Soundexchange has $100 million unclaimed royalties—there is
money to be had.
Rosenblatt: are creative upstarts any different from other
kinds of upstarts? We expect people starting out to do their homework to make a
living—get a professional license if they need it, pay taxes. TurboTax is a
solution to what we expect from people.
A: does think tax code should be simplified; does get to
whether it’s the gov’ts role to act. Gov’t
may help make TurboTax available to poor people (or better, pre-fill the return
like they do in other countries).
Copyright’s Private Ordering: Lessons For Congress
Jennifer Rothman
Congress should largely leave room for private ordering, but
sometimes codify uniformly accepted norms and support private ordering/avoid
calcification.
Different attempts to address uncertainty in law/uncertainty
about fair use: arguments that it’s more predictable than some say, but in
individual cases it’s still uncertain so risk-averse people will still license.
Campbell is an object lesson in why
you should license—district court reversed by court of appeals reversed by
Supreme Court, which remanded; ultimately settled with licensing fee—in practice
this was a total loss for 2 Live Crew.
She worries about courts interpreting risk aversion as customary
licensing practice worth respecting: her favorite example is Ringgold, where a poster was on screen
for less than 30 seconds, but court found unfair in part because it bucked an
industry custom of licensing set dressing.
We could revise §107 to limit on reliance on customary
licensing, use guidelines and alternative licensing. Not saying that licensing shouldn’t be
relevant—availability, feasibility and reasonableness of licensing is relevant.
But that’s different from whether people usually license or usually don’t
license in an industry.
Use guidelines trying to address uncertainty: the Classroom
Guidelines developed after Congress threw up its hands. This didn’t turn out
well. Negotiated by authors and
publishers mostly; didn’t include educators, students, or universities; courts
have often incorporated them despite their unrepresentativeness and have used
them as a ceiling on fair use. We might want to codify some changes: don’t use
their violation to determine whether something is fair use; maybe try again
with representative group.
Best Practices largely coming out of AU: valiant effort to
push back against clearance culture. Done some important work, but concerned
about codifying them as standard in particular industries. Again, they’re not
representative of large content owners whose content is most likely to be used.
Documentary guidelines can be more limiting than necessary, like not allowing cutting
to the beat in incidentally captured music or creating a work around a
copyrighted work.
Alternative regimes on top of copyright: Creative Commons—also
a reaction to fair use uncertainty.
Allows authors to express what uses they think are appropriate. Maybe we
just want Congress to leave this alone—w/exceptions: codify favoring
attribution for fair use analysis (maybe even safe harbors); clarify that
violation of private contract doesn’t alter analysis of infringement v. fair
use. Documentary filmmakers often can’t comply with CC; they shouldn’t be
hesitant to make fair use anyway.
Technology/contracts altering ©’s boundaries, technology and
DRM—private agreements like Content ID.
We should restrict the ability of tech and private party agreements to
eliminate fair use. © can leave
breathing room for private ordering and experimentation, but adopt good ideas.
Other good ideas: faculty ownership of scholarship and
course materials, a universally accepted norm that nonetheless seems to run
afoul of WFH; maybe attribution should be a requirement; a la carte copyright
where you can register and choose to allow, say, educational use. © can protect against lock-in effect; protect
fair use from obsolescence; support fair use.
Clarify whether transformativeness requires content change or just
purpose. Additional safe harbors; limit
scope of statutory damages in certain circumstances, esp. where people
erroneously predict that use will be fair.
Q: what about webcasting v. streaming in §114? Private streaming services’ deals—a lot of
the terms end up mimicking the terms in webcasting, even the weird performance
complement rules; public/private distinction gets blurred.
A: in general there’s a lot of interplay, and there’s not a
bright line—operates in the shadow of the law. Warps in response to law; we
need what Kozinski was talking about, interplay with courts and legislature.
Gordon: do you have in mind a sort of anti-DMCA: if you use
tech improperly we can stop you?
A: Does interplay w/DMCA in gov’t authority.
Q: PTO roundtable suggestion—require tech to leave breathing
room for some use of works—e.g., let’s have at least 5 seconds of a work up,
not auto takedown even if tech permits.
Secondary Copyright Remedies
Felix Wu
Proposal: Remedies for secondary © infringement should be
more limited than remedies for direct infringement, whatever they are. Statute doesn’t codify secondary liability at
any point, leaving no room for judges who expound on secondary liability to
provide for different remedies.
Relation to tech innovation.
Why not borrow from patent law?
Patent specifically defines secondary infringement, but the relation between
infringement and innovation is different in © and patent. Courts borrowing from
patent face a very different context—misborrowing. In patent, the statute speaks of articles w/
no substantially noninfringing use. It’s not possible for tech to relate to the
underlying ©ed work in the same way. What would it mean for something to be
specifically adapted to infringe a
specific work, as the patent statute requires? The tech is always capable of processing
public domain/authorized works. Taken seriously, there’d be no contributory
infringement at all.
That’s not where we’ve gone.
This concept is not a nullity in patent because tech innovation is
wrapped up in the primary monopoly we grant to patentee, and orthogonal to
primary monopoly we grant to copyright owner.
Thus secondarily liable actor is differently positioned than primarily
liable actor.
Second concern: free expression. Protect tech/platforms
because of externalities they create. That by itself can’t be enough to protect
secondary actors more than primary actors, who also often exercise some kind of
speech right. But the primary actors get
benefits that are difficult to transfer to secondary actors—primary actor is
willing to take on more risk than secondary actor, since primary actor receives
sense of belonging/creativity/community that they can’t monetize and
transfer. Thus externalities will be
greater for platform.
Why not an immunity? Might be right in certain
circumstances, but not all. Free
expression is at the fore w/r/t §230.
But in © we might be concerned about uncompensated harm/mass
infringement. Platforms could be
least-cost avoiders in screening out infringement. Potential for moral hazard: immunity means
incentive to make money off of interest in infringing works.
What can we do to avoid overdeterrence? (1) Reduce/eliminate statutory damages for
secondary liability. (2) Give restitution/disgorgement but limit their ultimate
exposure. (3) Shift burden of proof from
defendants in calculation of damages/profits to avoid overcompensating Ps. May
not be possible to show effects of one particular copy, but secondary liability
cases are generally large in scope.
Lemley: run away from restitution. Damages would be worse. You mean disgorgement
w/causation. Too easy in remedies for
disgorgement to be all your profits.
May not need statutory change. Statute is silent on remedies
for secondary infringement.
A: courts don’t think they’re creating secondary liability
out of whole cloth—meaning of what counts as an exclusive right/triggering full
panoply of damages. But sees potential. He wants to use profits as a ceiling and shift the burden of proof to avoid
that problem with disgorgement.
Q: curious about moving away from patents. If you’re saying
anything that could be used to infringe © could be used for public domain
works, you’re begging the Q of whether that use is substantial. Is that really different
from patent?
A: substantiality is really small in patent—you could use
this item as a doorstop = that’s not substantial. Value of use for that purpose
is what courts look at. In ©, using it for public domain would have value.
RT: In terms of why
not an immunity: You give three reasons, but none of them seems to differ from
§230 to me. Even w/respect to “mass
infringement,” many of the actors that people hate in the §230 context do
aggregate gossipy/defamatory content or revenge porn, and most of the visitors
are happy to consume lots of different humiliations, which is the business
model of those sites.
A: interest in
speech is different as between those types of content—© is less speechy. I know you disagree.
No comments:
Post a Comment