American Meat Institute v. U.S. Dep’t of Agriculture, No.
13-5281 (D.C. Cir. July 29, 2014)
The D.C. Circuit here, en banc, upholds country of origin
labeling (COOL) requirements for meat, and in the process holds that Zauderer’s standard for compelled
commercial disclosures does not require the government interest at issue to be
the prevention of deception. This holding, however, reveals deep divides among
the judges about compelled commercial disclosures, with both concurrences and
dissents that try to frame the issue differently—looking ahead to the
inevitable cert petition.
Congress required COOL on many foods, including some meat
products, and passed a law defining “country of origin” for meat to be based on
where the animal had been born, raised, and slaughtered—the three major
production steps. After a WTO panel found the first implementing regulations to
violate our international obligations (they allowed multiple countries to be
listed, and further allowed commingling of meat from animals of different
origins as long as the label listed all the countries from which the animals
might have come), the Secretary promulgated a rule requiring more precise
information on the location of each production step. The new rule also eliminated the flexibility
allowed in labeling commingled animals, which promises increased costs for
certain operators. (Here’s another
variant of the First Amendment as Lochner:
it’s a labeling rule, but it will demand changes in production practices so
that producers can actually identify the thing that needs to be labeled; this
is an economic regulation, but its output is information, so now it’s a First
Amendment problem. But the producers’
objection isn’t really to the compelled speech; it’s to the expense of
implementing the new production practices required of them.)
AMI argued that Zauderer
didn’t apply to government interests other than preventing consumer protection,
and that this regulation flunked Central
Hudson. The parties agreed that Zauderer
applied to mandatory disclosure of “purely factual and uncontroversial information”
appropriate to prevent deception in the regulated party’s commercial speech. What
of purely factual and uncontroversial disclosures serving other government
interests? AMI argued that even if Zauderer did extend that far, the
government had no substantial interest in COOL.
Zauderer itself
isn’t clear; the government’s interest in that case, and the subsequent Milavetz case was in preventing
deception, and thus the language could simply have conformed to that. However, the language Zauderer used to justify its approach was far broader. Zauderer
rejected Central Hudson analysis as
unnecessary in light of the “material differences between disclosure
requirements and outright prohibitions on speech.” The Court continued: “the
First Amendment interests implicated by disclosure requirements are
substantially weaker than those at stake when speech is actually suppressed.” The
speaker’s interest was “minimal”: “Because the extension of First Amendment
protection to commercial speech is justified principally by the value to
consumers of the information such speech provides, appellant’s constitutionally
protected interest in not providing any particular factual information in his
advertising is minimal.” These reasons seem “inherently applicable beyond the
problem of deception,” and the en banc majority noted that other circuits have
so found.
Okay then. Is the
government’s interest in COOL adequate?
AMI disparaged the interest at stake as merely satisfying consumers’
“idle curiosity.” The Supreme Court
hasn’t told us whether a Zauderer-passing
interest has to qualify as “substantial” under Central Hudson, and anyway what counts as a substantial interest “itself
seems elusive.” However, several aspects
of COOL for food combined to make a substantial interest: “the context and long
history of country-of-origin disclosures to enable consumers to choose
American-made products; the demonstrated consumer interest in extending
country-of-origin labeling to food products; and the individual health concerns
and market impacts that can arise in the event of a food-borne illness
outbreak.”
COOL has “an historical pedigree that lifts it well above
‘idle curiosity,’” dating to 1890.
“[T]he ‘time-tested consensus’ that consumers want to know the
geographical origin of potential purchases has material weight in and of
itself.” The value of this information
is a matter of common sense.
Congresspeople identified the statute’s purpose as “enabling customers
to make informed choices based on characteristics of the products they wished
to purchase, including United States supervision of the entire production
process for health and hygiene.” Some
believed that COOL would lead to consumers choosing to buy American. “Even though the production steps abroad for
food imported into the United States are to a degree subject to U.S. government
monitoring, it seems reasonable for Congress to anticipate that many consumers
may prefer food that had been continuously under a particular government’s
direct scrutiny.”
Congresspeople also indicated that people “would have a
special concern about the geographical origins of what they eat.” The legislative history refers to “the
collapse of the cantaloupe market when some imported cantaloupes proved to be
contaminated and consumers were unable to determine whether the melons on the
shelves had come from that country.” This anecdote “more broadly suggests the
utility of these disclosures in the event of any disease outbreak known to have
a specific country of origin, foreign or domestic.” (This discussion is conducted in a weird
vacuum, with no mention of just how few USDA inspectors there are and just how
little food gets inspected—here and elsewhere.
Is it ironic that many of the people who might buy American based on
assumptions about superiority may well have voted for representatives who have
made American origin less and less a guarantee of safe and hygenic production?)
Surveys in the record indicated that 71-73% of consumers
would be willing to pay for COOL. Though
consumers tend to overstate their willingness to pay, these studies, plus the
many favorable comments received during rulemaking, reinforced the historical
basis for treating such information as valuable.
This will be important later: The interests served by the
rule were those advanced by Congress when it adopted the statute, even if the
agency didn’t discuss those interests.
In defense of this position, the en
banc majority stated that it didn’t want to allow “perfectly adequate
legislative interests properly stated by congressional proponents” to be “doomed
by agency fumbling (whether deliberate or accidental),” because that rule would
“allow the executive to torpedo otherwise valid legislation simply by failing
to cite to the court the interests on which Congress relied,” and allow the
next President to reinstate a regulation by citing the right interests. “We do
not think the constitutionality of a statute should bobble up and down at an
administration’s discretion.”
Anyway, the agency sufficiently invoked the relevant
interests. Agency statements from prior rulemakings claiming that COOL serves
no food safety interest weren’t inconsistent with the government’s litigation
position. “Simply because the agency
believes it has other, superior means to protect food safety doesn’t
delegitimize a congressional decision to empower consumers to take possible
country-specific differences in safety practices into account.” (Compare this idea to the Pom Wonderful statement that the FDA
isn’t as expert about consumer understanding as market participants are. When regulators fail to protect us, who can
take up the slack, and how?)
Given an adequate interest, the remaining Zauderer question is whether the regulation
fits the interest. The en banc majority comments that the Zauderer test “differs in wording,
though perhaps not significantly in substance,” from the Central Hudson test, at least on these facts. Central
Hudson would require the court to determine whether “the regulatory
technique [is] in proportion to [the] interest,” an inquiry comprised of
assessing whether the chosen means “directly advance[s] the state interest
involved” and whether it is narrowly tailored to serve that end. A Central
Hudson analysis commonly requires evidence of a regulation’s effectiveness,
but “such evidentiary parsing is hardly necessary when the government uses a
disclosure mandate to achieve a goal of informing consumers about a particular
product trait.” Zauderer is like res ipsa
loquitur: “by acting only through a reasonably crafted disclosure mandate,
the government meets its burden of showing that the mandate advances its
interest in making the ‘purely factual and uncontroversial information’
accessible to the recipients.” The
disclosure must however relate to the good or service offered by the regulated
party.
The majority also commented that “[t[he self-evident
tendency of a disclosure mandate to assure that recipients get the mandated
information may in part explain why, where that is the goal, many such mandates
have persisted for decades without anyone questioning their
constitutionality.” COOL isn’t the only
required disclosure about product attributes—others include fiber content, care
instructions for clothing items, and listing of ingredients.
“Notwithstanding the reference to ‘narrow tailoring,’ the
Court has made clear that the government’s burden on the final Central Hudson factor is to show a
‘reasonable fit,’ or a ‘reasonable proportion,’ between means and ends.” When the government’s interest is to ensure
that consumers receive particular information, this means-ends fit is “self-evidently
satisfied when the government acts only through a reasonably crafted mandate to
disclose ‘purely factual and uncontroversial information’ about attributes of
the product or service being offered.”
Mandatory disclosures will therefore almost always have a reasonable
means-ends relationship, unless disclosure is unduly burdensome in a way that
chills protected speech.
Applying Zauderer
here, the disclosures were “purely factual and uncontroversial information”
about the good or service being offered. AMI objected to the word “slaughter,” but the
court didn’t need to address its objections because the rule allows retailers
to use “harvested” instead, and AMI didn’t object to that. AMI also didn’t disagree with the truth of
the facts to be disclosed, so they weren’t controversial “in that sense.” Nor was COOL controversial “in the sense that
it communicates a message that is controversial for some reason other than
dispute about simple factual accuracy.”
Some required factual disclosures could be so one-sided or incomplete
that they wouldn’t qualify as “factual and uncontroversial” (note: but not
abortion disclosures; never those), but not these. (Note the tension with the idea that
consumers could believe that foreign countries might provide dangerous food.) COOL doesn’t require corporations to carry
messages biased against or expressly contrary to the corporation’s views. Nor
is it so detailed that it effectively rules out ordinary advertising methods. As a result, the government’s interests here
were sufficient to sustain COOL under Zauderer.
I'm betting that if it gets to SCOTUS, they uphold. And I say this in a purely cynical sense - they personally will be able to identify countries of origin they personally want to avoid. So they'll understand the need for labeling.
ReplyDeleteGK
That thought occurred to me too.
ReplyDelete