Under NY GBL § 518, a vendor who wants to impose a surcharge
for using a credit card to compensate for the credit card companies’ surcharges
risks criminal prosecution if it labels its credit card price a surcharge
rather than advertising that it offers a discount for using cash. The court found this restriction
unconstitutional. Section 518 provides:
“No seller in any sales transaction may impose a surcharge on a holder who
elects to use a credit card in lieu of payment by cash, check, or similar
means.” Everyone agreed, however that
the statute didn’t bar “discounts” for cash.
A surcharge for credit and a discount for cash are, in
theory, equivalent. But consumer
psychology is different: “consumers perceive credit-card surcharges negatively
as a kind of loss or penalty, while cash discounts are perceived positively as
a kind of gain or bonus.” (Citing, inter
alia, my colleage Adam Levitin—albeit
misspelling his name.) Plaintiffs argued
that “surcharge” was “an accurate and effective way to convey to consumers that
paying with credit is actually more expensive than paying with cash,” given
that the prices charged to merchants by credit card companies are among the
largest and fastest-growing expenses for some merchants. (Citing Levitin
again.) Using “surcharge” would,
they argued, make consumers more likely to notice the fees and act to avoid
them, producing downward pressure on the credit card fees, known as “swipe
fees.” When notice of surcharges was
permitted in Australia, swipe fees there declined significantly. Without using surcharges labeled as such, “some
retailers cannot effectively call consumers’ attention to the price differences
between cash and credit, and therefore must charge higher headline prices for
everyone.” Thus, surcharge bans force
cash users to subsidize credit card users’ purchases, and this is a problem
insofar as cash users tend to be disproportionately poor and minority. The yearly subsidy from cash-using households
has been estimated at $149, with $1333 transferred to each card user.
Defendants responded that the surcharge ban protected
consumers from unfair surprise and deception, because consumers “tend to plan
and anchor their expectations around the advertised sticker price of a given
item they intend to purchase.” A consumer who later learns of a discount isn’t
harmed, but if she learns of an additional charge for using credit, her
expectations can be frustrated.
Credit card companies used to ban price differences by
contract. Then Congress amended TILA to
bar that practice, but enacted a ban on using
the word surcharge, as GBL § 518 did.
That law lapsed in 1984, which led the credit card companies to lobby
states to enact similar laws, which was the genesis of § 518; credit card
companies also barred use of “surcharge” by contract. In 2013, Visa and MasterCard agreed to drop
these prohibitions as part of a larger antitrust settlement.
The plaintiff businesses paid swipe fees and would like to
charge higher prices for credit. But
they contended that framing this as a cash discount “would make advertised
prices look higher than they are, without making it transparent that the higher
price would be due solely to credit card transaction costs -- precisely the
information [they] wish to convey to [their] consumers.” Four of the five businesses thus simply
charged the same price for all transactions.
The fifth used to post a sign that informed customers of a 3% additional
charge for credit, until informed by a lawyer-customer that this was
illegal. It still charged more for
credit, without characterizing that as a surcharge or extra charge for credit
as opposed to a discount for cash.
Defendants argued that § 518 was an anti-fraud law barring
“surcharges” that were increases over the “regular price,” and that the
“regular price” was the price communicated to consumers. Thus, defendants
argued, if the credit card price was displayed at least as conspicuously as the
cash price, then the credit card price would be the “regular price” and there’d
be no violation of the law. Some of the
plaintiffs, defendants argued, didn’t propose to advertise credit card prices
any less prominently than cash prices, and thus lacked standing. However, several plaintiffs did want to
advertise their surcharges only as a percentage fee on top of their cash
prices, and would violate defendants’ reading of the statute. In any event, the court rejected defendants’
“rather convoluted interpretation” of the statute, which on its face simply
banned surcharges and thus chilled retailers from characterizing their prices
as surcharges without providing guidance on how prominently prices had to be
displayed. The court found that there
was a real risk of prosecution, as New York had enforced the law before, even
against someone who testified that his signs clearly stated both the cash price
and the credit price, and against people who didn’t post prices but only
announced them orally. While the
(lapsed) federal definitions were designed to permit two-tier pricing systems
as long as consumers were exposed to the highest price when they saw a tagged
or posted price, New York hadn’t adopted those definitions.
After Sorrell v. IMS
Health, content-based restrictions on speech require heightened scrutiny
and are presumptively invalid, even for commercial speech (even though that
category is defined by its content).
Under Caronia, criminal laws
warrant even more careful scrutiny.
Plaintiffs argued that §518 restricted speech based on its content:
describing an extra charge as a surcharge.
Defendants responded that §518 only regulated nonexpressive conduct,
imposing a surcharge, and that in the alternative it only imposed a disclosure
requirement, which required only rational basis review.
The court agreed with the plaintiffs. The law drew the line
between prohibited surcharges and permissible discounts based on words and
labels, not economic realities. Anyway,
even under defendants’ reading, the law still violated the First
Amendment. Though sellers could set the
credit card price at any level they wanted, that was the conduct at issue; the
speech was in how they communicated that price.
“Pricing is a routine subject of economic regulation, but the manner in
which price information is conveyed to buyers is quintessentially expressive,
and therefore protected by the First Amendment.” (And the manner in which price information is conveyed can pretty easily misleading, given the many
ways in which prices can be gamed, but we’re not worrying about that right
now.)
The argument that § 518 was just a disclosure rule also
failed. Under the law, disclosure wasn’t
sufficient; the statute also barred sellers “from advertising their cash price
in a way that causes consumers to perceive it as the regular, baseline price
against which all other prices are measured.”
By comparison, Minnesota’s surcharge law simply required a seller to
inform the buyer of the surcharge both orally at the time of sale and by a
conspicuously posted sign. (Of course,
that doesn’t really deal with the bait and switch issue of the consumer who’s
already decided to buy then having to accept the higher price or leave, unless
we assume—contrary to most of what we know about consumer behavior—that
consumers read those signs. Compare the
litigation about the practice of posting “prices,” then charging consumers ablanket percentage over the posted price at checkout no matter what form of
payment they used—the stores using that practice claimed that they did disclose
it on signs in the store, but unsurprisingly it was still deceptive. A real disclosure law would require posting
cash price/credit price together.) The
court reasoned that a seller “who fully complied with Minnesota’s disclosure
requirement would still violate defendants’ reading of section 518 if it
displayed its cash price one iota more prominently than the credit card price.”
That makes it an anti-disclosure statute, because it bars disclosures of cash
prices “even marginally more conspicuously” than credit prices. (By that standard, the FTC’s disclosure
guidelines seem to be anti-disclosure guidelines as well, since they bar adding
distractors to an ad that divert consumers from any required disclosures.) Because § 518 was an outright bar on speech,
the relaxed standard of Zauderer was
inapplicable.
Thus, intermediate scrutiny applied, and § 518 failed
it. The court therefore didn’t reach
plaintiffs’ argument that listing the
prices of their goods and services wasn’t commercial speech, but shockingly
indicated that it was inclined to agree.
Though commercial speech generally “does no more than propose a
commercial transaction,” or is “related solely to the economic interests of the
speaker and its audience,” and though price information “no doubt proposes a
transaction and relates to economic interests,” this was “more than just a
debate about how best to sell toothpaste,” whatever that means. Plaintiffs wanted to explain why prices were
at the level they were and who was responsible for that. “Given current debates over swipe fees and financial regulation more generally,
those questions have a powerful noncommercial valence” (emphasis added). (WTF?
Look, there are debates about whether fluoride is dangerous and how to
preserve dental hygiene “more generally”; that doesn’t mean “our toothpaste has
flouride” is noncommercial speech. This
interpretation of “does no more than propose a commercial transaction” empties
the category, since all proposals of commercial transactions implicitly and
necessarily make arguments about why a person ought to have certain preferences
or satisfy those preferences in a certain way.)
Anyhow, intermediate scrutiny: dual pricing was lawful in
itself, and the speech covered was non-misleading. Though surcharges might be misleading if they
were hidden or inadequately disclosed, the cases teach that potentially
misleading information can’t absolutely be banned if it can be presented in a
nondeceptive way. There was nothing
“inherently misleading” about describing a price difference as a credit
surcharge or about displaying a
credit price “with marginally less prominence than the cash price.” Truthfully and effectively conveying the true
costs of using credit cards could actually make consumers more informed rather
than less.
(Look, I’m actually hugely sympathetic with the outcome
here, except for that endorsement of displaying a credit price less
prominently. But this rationale is
pretty misleading: the court is equivocating about who bears that “true
cost.” If I’m using credit, the “true
cost” is a big benefit to me, according to the court’s own evidence. It’s the dynamic effects that make a difference,
once retailers feel that they can get away with charging a “surcharge” where
they couldn’t be bothered to give a “discount,” given the realities of consumer
behavior. And those realities, not for
nothing, indicate that consumers are not computers, which means we ought to
recognize that displaying the credit price less prominently could easily confuse consumers even if
it “shouldn’t”—the use of “discount for cash” instead of “surcharge for credit”
shouldn’t affect consumers, but it
plainly does.)
Compared to credit card surcharges aren’t misleadingly
presented, §518 “perpetuates consumer confusion by preventing sellers from
using the most effective means at their disposal to educate consumers about the
true costs of credit-card usage.” Thus,
the law doesn’t directly advance consumer protection interests.
Also, §518 was riddled with numerous “exemptions and
inconsistencies [that] bring into question the purpose” of the statute. The bait-and-switch concern offered by
defendants applied only to credit card surcharges, not other additional
charges, and thus the law didn’t actually protect them, “since handling
charges, shipping costs, service fees, processing fees, ‘suggested tips,’ and
any number of other types of additional charges -- which consumers may or may
not be able to take steps to avoid -- may still be added on top.” Plus, New York exempted itself and some favored utilities from the statute, indicating that
it wanted to escape the blame of
higher prices but didn’t want to let other sellers do so. “Defendants offer no explanation for why
credit-card surcharges are somehow less deceptive when imposed by the Water
Board, for example, than when imposed by ordinary commercial retailers like the
plaintiffs.”
In addition, §518 was far broader than necessary to serve
anti-fraud goals; New York could easily have regulated only surcharges that
were deceptive or misleading, or it could have used Minnesota’s model. Anyway, New York already had laws barring
false advertising and deceptive acts and practices. Thus, § 518 was overbroad and violated the
First Amendment.
It was also impermissibly vague, since it failed to provide
adequate notice of what was barred, as defendants interpreted it. Making liability turn on the labels sellers
used to describe their prices was impermissible because careful or
sophisticated sellers could avoid liability by using “discount for cash” while
more careless ones would be liable for using “credit price.” (I don’t know why this is vague as opposed to
credit card-company-favoring but ok.)
The narrowing interpretation offered by defendants—credit prices had to
be displayed at least as prominently as cash prices—would present a closer
question, but was too far from the statutory text to matter.
The court found that whether §518 was preempted as
anticompetitive by the Sherman Act presented a factual question that couldn’t
be resolved at this stage of the case.
Your article suggests that a discount for cash and a surcharge for credit are economically equivalent. They are not. If I buy a book for cash I receive only a book; if I buy a book for credit I receive a book and a loan. Consequently advertising 'discount for cash' is dishonest as I lose the benefit of the loan.
ReplyDeleteAnon: if the alternative is "surcharge for credit," then they are still economically identical, as the surcharge over the cash price replaces the discount from the credit price. Someone who prizes the loan may have to decide whether the loan is worth the surcharge/cash discount, but that's true in either case, once the retailer decides to charge different prices. The fact that people don't understand the economic equivalence is what produces the weird dynamic effects.
ReplyDelete