When I was younger, I had a shirt that had VE RI OLD in the traditional Harvard shield configuration. The local burrito place just rolled these out, and I love them:
Tuesday, February 28, 2023
COVID-related communications are ads where they tout D's services
Steven A. Conner DPM, P.C. v. Fox Rehabilitation Servs.,
P.C., 2023 WL 2226781, No. 2:21-cv-1580-MMB (E.D. Pa. Feb. 24, 2023)
Conner is a podiatrist who uses a fax machine at his
practice for treating patients, primarily as a communication destination for
incoming lab results. Fox offers a variety of physical, occupational and speech
therapy services in the form of house-calls to patients; it receives patients through,
among other things, referrals from doctors.
The question was whether eight faxes that Dr. Conner’s
practice received from Fox during the early days of the COVID-19 pandemic were
illegal junk faxes (“unsolicited advertisements”) under the federal
Telecommunications and Consumer Protection Act of 1991.
Each fax contained the headline “Helping Flatten The Curve
With House Calls.” Fox’s defense was that, with the healthcare system in
disarray, Fox wanted to reassure its partners and providers that Fox was open
for business and its services could be counted on. There was testimony that, in
the early days of the pandemic, many of Fox’s referral sources had reached out
to Fox asking for information, and that Fox was primarily seeking to inform
providers that Fox was adhering to existing COVID guidelines. The costs of the
fax campaign ultimately came out of Fox’s informational technology budget
because of its internal status as an information communication.
Out of the roughly 20,000 recipients, less than thirty
requested Fox to stop sending such faxes. Two healthcare office managers
testified that they had received Fox’s faxes and found them to be very helpful
in assuring their own practices that Fox remained open for business, was
comporting with COVID protocols and was “taking steps to bring additional
services to my attention.” They also testified that they did not see the faxes
as advertisements because the faxes “weren’t trying to sell me something” and
they “state things helpful to my practice.”
The TCPA defines an “unsolicited advertisement” as being
“any material advertising the commercial availability or quality of any
property, goods, or services which is transmitted to any person without that
person’s prior express invitation or permission, in writing or otherwise.” Dr.
Conner credibly testified that he did not give permission to Fox to send the
faxes. “Liability must be based on an objective standard—neither the intentions
of the sender nor the opinions of the recipient factor into the equation.” The
Third Circuit has also stated that courts can spot illegal junk faxes by considering
if the advertisement has “profit as an aim,” if it promotes a discount or
price, if it comes with a sales contact, or if it contains “testimonials,
product images, or coupons.” The FCC has also defined non-offensive fax
messages that contain only “information” as opposed to commercial promotion: “[F]acsimile
communications that contain only information, such as industry news articles,
legislative updates, or employee benefit information, would not be prohibited
by the TCPA rules.”
The court held that the larger context of the pandemic wasn’t
part of the objective test for what was an ad; the “reasonable recipient”
standard “considers only that material contained within the four-corners of the
fax.”
The court held that it was clear
that all eight faxes are promoting
Fox’s services in a way that suggests … Fox is trying to secure referrals from
providers. The faxes tout a specific “model” of care used by Fox and which Fox
describes as high quality and unique. While the faxes certainly describe
capabilities of Fox’s services as they pertain to dealing with the challenges
of COVID, that is still a promotion of quality and not solely and informational
exercise.
Even the first fax, which posed the closest question, was not just informational:
[W]hile the majority of the fax
message appears to be on the informational side, it still promotes qualities of
Fox’s proprietary “house call” model, trademarked and therefore presumably
proprietary of Fox. The bullet points describe the quality of Fox’s
services—even though these descriptions are within the context of dealing with
the challenges of the pandemic, they are still promoting the commercial quality
of the services offered. Here—and with the other seven faxes—there is an
embedded profit motive to gain referrals from past providers, because the more
referrals Fox receives the more revenue they are hoping to receive from the
patients’ insurance.
Subsequent faxes went further, promoting the proprietary
“Fox Model” for treatment of patients and going beyond just informing the
recipient that was open for business or even that Fox was adhering to
COVID-preventive protocols. Having a middle informational segment that would be
fine on its own didn’t change the advertising nature of the whole fax.
Promoting new capabilities wasn’t just “informational,” even if they were health-related.
The court also rejected a First Amendment challenge to the TCPA.
But the court didn’t find willfulness entitling Conner to enhanced
damages; “Fox’s witnesses were credible when they testified that their intent
was to inform their past referral providers of their additional COVID capabilities,
not to gain referrals in spite of TCPA restrictions.”
Saturday, February 25, 2023
Fourteenth Trademark Scholars' Roundtable, part 3 (Evidence)
Changes in Trademark Law and Evidentiary Rules
Introduction: Jake
Linford
Before courts admitted surveys routinely, they were
concerned about hearsay. Sometimes rejecting surveys seems like judicial notice—“cola”
as generic; the court doesn’t want to hear contrary survey evidence. Some objections
go to the weight of the evidence.
Instead of surveys, can we look at things like Google
results or large text databases reflective of use in a particular community? Comicon
case: corpus linguists filed a brief trying to establish how comicon was used prior
to the first San Diego Comicon; court didn’t find that persuasive but shows
possibilities of use. You can get a sense for what the use of the putative mark
was like at first use, if your data are rich enough. If survey evidence isn’t
at the right time (Coach’s claim of fame in the Coach case), corpus evidence
might be able to fix that problem. Skeptical that it could help w/confusion
though.
Brain scans for consumers? New article proposes judging
similarity—he’s very skeptical both of cost and whether it tells us anything
[we don’t already know]. What about ChatGPT? Skeptical of that too.
If courts rely too much on dictionaries, the corpus evidence
might create a wedge b/t judge and dictionary.
Barton Beebe: How to integrate this into a larger rethinking
of competition? At the origin (in technical TM times), confusion wasn’t the
harm sought to be addressed; confusion was the evidence of the harm sought to
be addressed, which was trespass to property rights. What would it mean if we
said TM law is primarily concerned with promoting competition: what would a
survey look like for infringement? [Unsurprisingly, I say it would have to
consider materiality.] Would secondary meaning surveys change? Maybe not. But
would consumer uncertainty play a role in our understanding of how preventing
confusion promotes competition?
Earliest surveys—1921 Coca-Cola v. Chera-Cola, used as a
matter of course a Q including what we now call a Likert scale, measuring level
of certainty. So did 1923 survey. Then we lost that, especially w/ face to face
interviews. Surveys became trinary: yes/no/unsure—pushing people to a yes/no
answer. Most people are not really sure! These surveys are now designed to
suppress that uncertainty and not let it appear in the courtroom b/c we just
want numbers.
Imagine 20% confusion in a survey, but everyone was only
somewhat sure, while 80% are not confused at all and are absolutely certain. If
you present that nuanced distribution, maybe 20% isn’t enough b/c of the large
number of correct consumers. We urge introduction of that next level of detail
to that.
Also, materiality: this is a way to consider materiality in
the rubric of uncertainty.
How do we survey for arbitrariness, fancifulness, suggestiveness?
Discussant: Mark
Lemley
Maybe corpus linguistics can help w/things like
descriptiveness and nominative fair use, though skeptical about confusion or
fame (b/c you need a standard). Corpuses are attractive b/c the alternatives are
so bad: Surveys are infinitely manipulable; dictionaries have an opposite goal
to that of a statutory interpreter—to cover possible meanings instead of
correct one and so they are abused when used in legal settings.
Rogers is a rule of evidence; its goal is to replace
the cumbersome, problematic LOC multifactor analysis with a rule that irrebuttably
presumes no confusion except in limited circumstances. [At least the 9th
Cir. version.]
One possibility: what if we required or at least said a
presumptively admissible survey was X—could be drafted into court rules. If we
did that right, we could get rid of a lot of fighting back and forth and
manipulation and problematic Qs asking about permission. We could standardize
minimum percentages, affected by Likert scale. Could also give us an idea about
what heightened confusion is—having a standard would allow us to actually
heighten the standard in Rogers cases, which generally don’t actually do
so.
Statutory presumption of secondary meaning after five years
of exclusive use: it says literally that the Director “may” presume this. There’s
a nice naïve literalism that would say the PTO can do this but courts have no
power to do so: if the PTO hasn’t so presumed, courts are not in a position to
do so.
Incontestability: maybe we ought to have reverse
incontestability: if I’ve been around for a certain period of time, we presume
that I’m not interfering with another TM owner’s rights. Goes beyond laches;
would require killing Dawn Donut, which is an additional plus in his
view.
We might think about a TM anti-SLAPP provision.
Fromer: Deciding what we’re going to measure + how do we use
a new tool—new questions arise with each new type. Corpus linguistics: consider
fame. Is fame use of a word in a particular context a sufficient amount, or is
it that the word is only used in that context? We’ve never asked that before! How
do we know whether the use is shorthand for a class and what that means [what
the Google court called synechdoche use]. Sometimes survey formats get
standardized by default, so it has to be very thoughtful.
Grynberg: TM right now only has limited concern with mental
availability for confusion; courts normally talk about confusion even though TM
owners want to control availability of mark and surveys may be measuring that.
On Likert scale, a person w/high recognition and low certainty may be reflecting
a belief in what “belongs” to the TM owner.
Heymann: efficiency/cost trades off with accuracy in
surveys. People are notoriously bad at reporting on their own mental processes
and that’s what we’re asking them to do. [especially with “why do you say that?”
where they just guess.] In UX, we don’t ask people how they’d navigate a
website; we watch them do that. So we could construct a mock situation where we
ask people to make choices and derive from that whether they are confused or
not. Choices instead of thoughts.
Silbey: companies invest in those already!
Sprigman: could be a Squirt test with context.
Heymann: but actually ask them to perform the selection task,
not just report on what they think they’d do. We’d have to think about whether
hesitation counts.
RT: [Want to strongly endorse Fromer’s point: Measuring
almost always changes what the construct is—you are answering a different Q
than the non-surveyed or non-corpus analyzed question; the survey and the
corpus themselves answer different questions (what do people say in response to
direct Qs, sometimes after training, versus how do they talk when not thinking
about it?). Maybe it’s a better Q, but that needs to be identified.
UX point: 1-800-Contacts: 10th Circuit says look
at clickthrough rate to find maximum possible confusion—possibly there’s opportunity
to focus more on this.
Past work on how people walk around in a fog of confusion:
Jacob Jacoby did this work in the 1980s—20% of people misunderstand any given
factual claim in advertising! They walk around confused about sponsorship b/c
of their priors!
How to survey arbitrariness/TM function: Washingmachine.com
in booking.com—maybe along with not sure we also need the option “neither a
common name nor a brand name.”
Lemley’s proposed standardization: (1) Burrell’s caution
yesterday that they standardized badly, including about permission; (2) Teflon
is a pretty standard format, but questions always arise: (a) original Teflon
survey used STP as a well known brand name; wouldn’t do that now; (b) take a
look at FOOTLONG surveys, both of which were Teflon surveys w/essentially the
same Qs but different training and testing examples. 14 point swing in FOOTLONG
results—which might even seem reassuring about the general tenor of the answers
since even manipulation didn’t change a ton, but it was a lot.
McKenna: we have substantial standardization in Eveready,
Teflon, Squirt (garbage, but much less common), but there’s enormous
variability introduced by stimulus, control, universe, and those are extremely
hard if not impossible to standardize. What has happened in TM is fetishization
of confusion for its own sake: confusion is itself the harm. So one goal is to
push against that construct: things in the context of survey evidence need to
connect to marketplace behavior, and certainty/Likert scales can help with
that.
There’s a strain of marketing literature that uses scanner
data: tries to measure effect of brand extension on parent brand. And mostly
they don’t unless the products are used together; consumers just segment.
Marketing studies: what TM thinks of as related products, TM is much more
expansive than consumer behavior—things have to be really close together for consumers
to care. Mental state is relevant, but it is relevant in conjunction with
behavior.
Linford: if we’re right in our empirical work that
supposedly tarnishing uses often have a burnishing effect, what are firms doing
when they challenge those uses?
Sprigman: don’t assume firms are rational: they think it’s
theirs!
Linford: firms do try to figure out what marketing decisions
will work [but there is a difference between the expertise and methodology of
the person who does that at P&G and that of the person who does that at
Gucci—this is an example of high fashion possibly distorting our analysis of
other things].
Ivorine tooth-whitening gum & Ivory soap—the court didn’t
think that, as Ivory claimed, you could brush teeth with soap; court looked at
survey responses and heavily weighted the “I don’t know” responses against Ivory.
If we’re looking for marketplace harm, that is looking for
confusion—but in theory under current law we should be looking for the likelihood
of marketplace harm—evidence of likely changed behavior. How would we do
that?
Sheff: You could have rigorous standards about substitutes
and cross-elasticity of demand that could lead you to the proper universe for a
given survey. But one reason you think competition is good might be a deep
suspicion of private economic power, so anything that adds friction to that is
good. In that circumstance, neither universe nor stimuli selection might matter
very much; even confusion might not matter very much. We could do things like
market share analysis—but TM might not try to prevent copying others’ TMs in
general.
Ramsey: standardize by requiring Qs to separate out different
kinds of confusion?
McKenna: courts settled on a low percentage b/c this was
about an injury to the TM owner, and the Q was what we should care about. Thinking
about injury to TM owner as not the only Q could let us consider, as Sprigman
argues, the benefit to the other consumers (85% even) who have benefited from
the new option and would have to face loss of the information they got from D’s
use.
Fromer: things change over time: marketing channels mattered
more when the multifactor test was initially propounded; this makes
standardization a challenge (what do we do with increasing brand self-parody?).
McGeveran: as antitrust swings back towards power
containment and holistically about efficiency in the whole market rather than
whether a particular merger is efficient, that could change how you think about
TM’s competition goal. The narrative
about market concentration and power and the ways in which tech creates
bottlenecks instead of long tails suggest productive TM inquiries: when we say “competition”
in TM, it’s no longer clear what we’re talking about. New market entry
opportunities? Competition on store shelves like with private labels? How does
TM contribute to the shape of the whole market?
Bone: TM has always been about protecting sellers and
avoiding fraud on the public; fraud reflects a moral wrong. Our reconfiguration
has to take those into account.
Mid-Point Discussants: Eric Goldman
Antitrust is not a model of empirical evaluation at law, but
empirical evidence does matter across consumer law—formation of TOS. Does a
link to a privacy policy provide effective notice? One court says a reasonably
prudent smartphone consumer knows that an underlined blue link is a hyperlink—that’s
just made up; no survey evidence or consumer testimony, no literature. Chances
are the judges are not themselves reasonable smartphone users. So much of what we
talked about today are riffs on broader consumer law cases: what do we know and
how do we know it? Emoji evidence: courts are just, again, making it up. A “good”
emoji evidence case includes a statement from law enforcement saying “I’ve
worked this beat and I know how they talk.” That’s the best evidence they use
(and it’s bad!).
Chris Sprigman: need a way to account for consumer
heterogeneity, which is almost always what we see under the hood. Different from
saying that consumer belief is sovereign/a trump. Vintage Brand case: court
asks whether consumer belief about sponsorship/licensing should be taken
seriously or should be considered a legal conclusion about licensing. This isn’t
wholly empirical.
Stabs at a theory of competition: start w/ preferences. We’ve
been agnostic about them for a while, removing moralism from competition. One
form of private differentiation is as good as another; we don’t question why
consumers want something. But: Producers enjoy more surplus in differentiated
markets; consumers enjoy less. The response is that consumer surplus lost in
the form of price is gained in the form of differentiated preferences being satisfied
more closely. But is that true of a manufactured-by-marketing preference? To
say that in a room of economists is to risk being called an idiot, but that
doesn’t mean it’s wrong. People’s valuation of attribution depends on the frame—they
value it more if it’s an entitlement and less if they have to pay for it. This
isn’t super hard, but the response from economists is “who cares?” We set a
legal rule, create preferences, then satisfy them. We forget at the end of the
day that the preferences only arose from the entitlements created by the legal
rule. This is unsatisfying. The neo-Brandeisians say: the market has an organic
existence, which is not about people being induced to have preferences, but
manifesting them. That’s too innocent; people are convinced into preferences
all the time—but a highly engineered preference might not be as important to
satisfy. If we were to use that model of competition in TM and designing
surveys, we’d look for what would cause consumers to substitute—focus on source
primarily, and we’d need some sort of materiality requirement either as an element
of claim or a belief about source strong enough to undergird a choice in the
market.
Need more coordination about surveys, outside the context of
particular cases. Judges and survey experts need to be able to interact in ways
that make accepted surveys more credible.
TM surveys should be more incentive-compatible—in © has done
incentive-compatible experiments where people buy & sell things—these are
more reliable b/c people don’t tell you what they think but show you what they
do—their incentives and their behavior are compatible. Correct answers should
benefit participants more than incorrect one, which simulates the real world
better. Even if it’s getting the right chewing gum, something small is at stake
in the real world.
Robert Burrell
Looking behind curtain of preference satisfaction: it’s very
difficult to convince courts to do that. One possibility: makers of Nurofen
pain range were fined AU$10 million for having misled consumers for selling the
same product as different products for, e.g., period pain with huge price
differences. But Nurofen still has a massive price premium over generic
ibuprofen: is that ok? We need other examples to move the dial.
Double identity as a solution to evidentiary challenges: it
is in Art. 13 of TRIPS! He’s a fan of it for goods cases—seems to cause
relatively little harm and acts as an escape valve for the property intuition:
it defines what the “property” is. It doesn’t work so well for advertising!
Advertising can convey all sorts of nonconfusing messages, so we need robust
defensive doctrines to prevent undue harm in advertising, but there are ways to
design that.
Evidentiary problems exist everywhere, though they vary across
jurisdictions. When we look at what’s actually happening, we see courts getting
really uncomfortable w/certain evidence but we don’t use that to ask more general
questions about the quality of evidence. Particularly UK and Singapore,
acquired distinctiveness is a reliance standard for at least some forms of TMs
(trade dress)—don’t provide evidence of use, show me that consumers rely on
this to make decisions. The move to failure to function and away from acquired
distinctiveness might be a similar rule of evidence—we don’t trust the usual
proxies. But if we don’t trust them in trade dress, why do we ever trust them?
In Australia, occasional examples in which proxies for
secondary meaning are regarded as unreliable—e.g., consumers had to buy
a thing, as when everyone had to buy a set-top box to transition from analog to
digital. Massive sales aren’t enough to prove consumers care about manufacturer—similarly
with hand sanitizers and masks. But we don’t ask similar questions about shoes,
soap, rice, even though those are staples in the modern world.
Evidence of actual confusion: sometimes ignored b/c wrong
sort of person is giving answer or answer is so manifestly wrong. Anyone who
thought Nike would make toilet cleaner had an extreme and fanciful reaction,
according to SCt of Australia. Anyone who thought McDonald’s would make wine
was operating under an erroneous assumption.
Maybe consumers aren’t good at explaining their responses
not b/c of problems in articulation but b/c that’s not how they make decisions!
Might be worth looking comparatively—he previously thought German TM law loved
surveys, and that’s true for distinctiveness in general, but not in likely
confusion cases where they are verboten. Lack of trust plus commitment to
normative view of likely confusion. But the effect (answering Lemley Q) was to
broaden rights.
What about marketing experts? Do they have specialized
knowledge, or are they charlatans? Australia has debated that as well. Ongoing question
of admissibility of Wayback Machine evidence. Every now & then, more in the
UK than Australia, courts just assert things about how people shop. And damages
are often just asserted. At quotidian level, there’s just a plague of fake
evidence—e.g., invoices. In light of that, a narrow property rule makes more
sense; otherwise you should have to show real harm.
Silbey: to demand TM have a theory of competition is to
displace the consumer as sovereign in terms of what evidence matters. We’re not
measuring systems; these are private rights of action.
McKenna: but we structure private rights of action towards
systematic goals all the time—what counts as secondary meaning, w/in TM.
Silbey: if it’s not a market for lemons story, it’s a
consumer sovereignty story. All these tests arise out of and are reified at a
time when the story about what’s optimal in a market is a view of advertising as
beneficial/creating the best kind of consumer market.
Sheff: evidentiary rules depend on the theoretical
structure. Is a deceptive used car dealer competing fairly? Why does it matter
that he be honest? The problem is the seller has information the buyer doesn’t—that’s
a form of power that we think ought not to exist in consumer markets. Why do we
think that? It’s not b/c it’s inefficient to allow asymmetric info to be used,
but b/c we have a thicker theory of autonomy underlying market structure.
[McGeveran: or both!] Theories that are quite different can converge on certain
aspects of regulatory structure.
But the interesting thing is how we choose when they
diverge. If the problem of used cars is that falsities will cause markets to
fail, then some critics said to Akerlof that if he was right there should be no
market so he must not be right; the response is “this market is worse than it
could be.” That’s a comparative claim. We could take care of the market for
lemons if we forbade all ads and required plain packaging. [I don’t think
that’s true.] Why would that be worse than the market we have now? We have some
substantive notions of freedom and autonomy, including in commercial behavior,
that shape our idea of the appropriate comparator market and what type of
regulatory regimes are preferable which then informs what types of evidence
count.
Lemley: There’s a perfectly good information story: bad
information makes markets less efficient and decreases purchases. You don’t
need a new theory of TM.
Sheff: by the same token, there’s an efficiency story about
branding; if we only care about efficiency we’d have a lot more regulation of
persuasive advertising than we do.
RT: (1) Anti-ESG movement/anti-DEI movement—think not just
about progressivism but about challenges to preference formation from the
right. What interventions into the market are justified because preferences are
currently distorted? Who is distorting preferences or at least affecting
formation of preferences in way they have a vested right to do? If that’s the
wrong framing, why is it the wrong framing?
(2) In response to FTC actions against “results not typical,”
industry mounted defense of “results not typical” for weight loss products: consumers
are buying hope—even small chance might be material depending on circumstances,
which pushes back on the Likert scale?
(3) double identity and advertising: note that in the US
comparisons for house brands are often made on the bottle or package!
(4) False advertising has similar theories to those
discussed by Burrell in the US: misleading v. misunderstood; puffery and no
reasonable consumer would believe that e.g. Froot Loops have fruit in them. Also there are now two
cases
accepting the Nurofen-style deception theory in the US.
(5) periodic reminder that registration is not actually
consumer focused. If we thought of the US as at least half registration based
we would have to say that it’s at least half about competition. [Lemley says
that registration might not be about competition either, but it’s at least
closer.]
McKenna: the choice is not between satisfying preferences
and not, but which preferences we will have and who will satisfy them. There is
no neutral position. Economist move: it doesn’t matter where the preference
comes from—that is actually a sneaky way of prioritizing certain preferences,
since different preferences would have emerged under different rules. Pretending
there aren’t rules around who got to shape those preferences is itself
deceptive.
Dogan: economists are also rethinking things. What do we do
about the fact that medical professionals buy generic drugs but uninformed
consumers, often poor/resource-constrained, buy the brand names. So their behavior
probably doesn’t match their preferences in some other world—but with what do
we replace revealed preferences?
We also need to understand what’s happening within the 85%
of unconfused consumers—it may not be a loss to them; it may mean nothing to
them.
Gangjee: Registration system is focused not really on
consumers or on competition—by and large it’s a different project [I describe
it as businesses ordering their own relations]. There is a morality for that. Historically,
there was a moral account. If our drive is to more normative account, it’s a
hard thing to get right. First UK TM act: no registration for word-only marks
at all—totally normative belief that words had multiple uses. Retreat from
normative system over time. It was not competition, but availability to
producers of words to use to speak—very interesting different vision, replaced
by distinctiveness over time.
Friday, February 24, 2023
Fourteenth Trademark Scholars Roundtable, part 2
Session 2: Responding to Anachronisms
Introduction: Mike
Grynberg
VIP may tell us a lot about what the potentials are.
Incrementalism: read Lanham Act along with other things like its common law
foundations and First Amendment principles—not empty formalism; recognize
normative component of TM. Semi-autonomous body of law with some principles of
its own. Developments at SCt should give some pause about their reliability—textualism
shouldn’t be simplistic, but Romag looks like empty textualism. Gorsuch’s
opinion says the Lanham Act exercises considerable care in mens rea, which is
then picked up by Jack Daniels; redefining section 43 remedies. This is in
contrast to looking, as Leval did in Rescuecom, at what each change to the law
actually did (whether you like that outcome or not). Hana Financial: tacking as
a pure question of fact; Booking.com, the same. Questionable factfinding is a
big route of problems in Rogers cases—like district court ignoring criticisms
of P’s survey in VIP. Maybe TM automony is anachronistic as opposed to cts just
glomming on to a particular test and not looking at radiating effects on TM
system as a whole. Tam & Brunetti: wiping away bars and then putting pressure
on failure to function as the limit on registration.
Do we prefer reconfiguration? Hard to do without statutory
change. 1A and Article III standing are there, but worrisome; casualness over
stare decisis does suggest courts are willing to look at things from scratch—Vintage
Brands; Netchoice—everything might be up for grabs. Courts could very well adopt a property frame,
redefining what TM’s pluralism is about—free riding stories won’t go away, no
matter how much people in this room want them to.
Laura Heymann: Don’t conflate goals of system w/way system
is organized to achieve those goals. Does “brand personality” online change
what TMs are about? What are user rights for: Democratization of brand meaning;
access to luxury goods; something else? What does association mean in the age
of brand persona, and what cognitive processes if any are of concern?
Be willing to let go of shorthands: LOC is probably not a
useful concept for what TM is actually doing now; so too with distinctiveness
and source identification in a world of licensing and outsourcing and
merchandising.
Do we value easy to apply rules? Or more flexibility for new
tech and interests as they arise? Courts get outpaced by market. But maybe we
can learn from how other communities respond to changes—Twitter made retweeting
part of the system, finding ways to give credit; TikTok too. Study Amazon: what
do we learn from systems developed to serve some of the same purposes that are
changing much more quickly than Congress or courts can.
Scholarship: help courts feel free to be more flexible?
Discussants: Lisa
Ramsey
Constitutional analysis, not just courts but also Congress!
Shouldn’t be intermediate scrutiny on a case by case basis, but an overall
reconsideration of the goals of TM law. Display on front of T-shirt:
ornamental, decorative; have legislature consider purposes of TM and PTO as
well to be gatekeeper to protect public domain.
Lifeguard example of abuse: threatens lots of users of “Lifeguard”
on front of search; court denies attorneys fees when someone decided to fight
and raise valid defenses of abandonment via naked licensing, genericity, etc.; the
TM clamaint got out of it w/a covenant not to sue. Maybe more fees for
prevailing Ds. Audience, speaker, and message must be considered when
considering benefits of competition in marketplace of ideas.
Jessica Litman
Morphing of meaning over time complicates assessments of “anachronism.”
100 years ago, a TM was a fanciful or arbitrary word or symbol attached to a
good at the point of sale, and nothing else was a TM. Other things were
protected—by unfair competition. All the things we rail about were protected
then by courts in equity, but we didn’t need a failure to function doctrine very
much. Courts don’t know this, so when they are looking at the Lanham Act, not
only do we have difficulty remembering the words don’t mean the same things,
the people who wrote those words didn’t imagine they’d come to mean what they’ve
come to mean. Textualist courts tend to make flatly wrong assumptions about
what the Lanham Act was and was not trying to do. Makes it much more
complicated to figure out whether a doctrine is looking at the world through a
distorted lens b/c the world has changed.
Lemley: Logistics of this: one possibility is larger
paradigm project that says we’re outside of confusion and here’s a new set of
rules. Burrell points out the incentive is to write terrible rules, but there
are counter-incentives; why do we actually have these forms of protection, as
divorced from competition? Makes us articulate the answer to that question w/o
relying on things from earlier and narrower vision. Attracted to Ramsey’s idea
of using 1A, meaning that bad drafting can’t ruin it all for us. But how does
that get implemented? Courts regularly strike down claims as applied? That
still seems difficult. To be successful, it needs something like a Rogers equivalent
for different doctrines. Every time a court uses Rogers, it’s covertly holding
that it would be unconstitutional to apply a broader set of rights; we’re
tailoring the test with this in mind. But the test doesn’t say 1A every time;
you just use the test.
Ramsey: do it w/broad fair use/general rules.
Lemley: his instinct is for standards so that they adapt,
but he gets that people have different preferences.
Goldman: how do we know when a rule has become
anachronistic? If there’s no consensus, there’s no mechanism to move forward.
IIC—not possible to get movement in Congress; and common law is a one-way
ratchet. Sunsets are a way to avoid anachronism. But there’s no concept like
that in the common law. Stare decisis is instead a barrier.
RT: if you’re looking for speech protective tests that don’t
require individual case by case balancing, we do have them by adding elements
to the cause of action (e.g., we could add harm back in to the TM test):
defamation has these too; patent/false advertising interface requirement of knowing
the claim was meritless.
Linford: don’t trust legislatures to handle speech issues. Concerned
about industry carveouts that seem to have been typical in last 30 years of ©
Act.
Sprigman: Does uncertainty mean confusion? “I don’t know”
who puts this out could be claimed as confusion if you take that seriously.
That’s the shapeshifting quality of the concept of confusion. Deception would be
a different concept than confusion—confusion is too capacious a concept for what
we’re talking about.
Litman: Deception is closer to the original meaning of
confusion when we have now.
Ramsey: it’s in the purpose statement of the Lanhan Act!
Textualists should love this.
Burrell: technically in the UK, passing off requires
deception, and it hasn’t made one iota of difference, so don’t look there! It
wasn’t enough to show “I wonder,” but you had to show a positive assumption.
But what caused the distinction to collapse was that courts decided to accept
that evidence of wondering meant that there were other, unidentified customers
out there who would assume without wondering. Maybe that’s not enough for
deception.
Sprigman: Beebe & Sprigman just finished a project on
levels of certainty—it’s pretty heterogenous about what they expect. There are
cases making distinctions b/t deception and confusion (e.g. cases say that
inquiries are not evidence of confusion) but also authority for collapsing them
(cases that say they are evidence).
Beebe: would also change the term “consumer.” We should stop
referring to consumers. It’s a charged term that carries with it the whole law
& econ approach. Marketplace deception; Dustin Marlan proposes citizen; at
least “purchaser.”
All of TM law is now “branding” law, so he might just use
that term. We now use the part—TM—to stand for the whole—reputation.
McKenna: a whole bunch of other terms we use now to denominate
a category, like trade dress, that weren’t coherently defined under unfair
competition b/c there was no need to define it. After Wal-Mart, attempts by
parties to call anything trade dress show the wisdom of that—we used to have
one line that mattered (technical TM) but now that’s not true so we need a bunch
more terms.
I yield to know one in cynicism about changing words
changing outcomes, but deception has some things going for it—in particular,
deception tends to imply materiality. And it ties into harm. We have a whole bunch
of ideas about confusion that are hard to link to cognizable harm, but courts
tend to assume that confusion is itself harm. We have a whole body of law about
fraud, and you never win a fraud claim by showing that a person wondered about
something—you have to show that the person then changed their behavior as a
result.
McGeveran: You confused me is a much different accusation
than you deceived me.
McKenna: we can’t really mean that a state of uncertainty is
actionable—if we did, “I don’t know whether X makes this” would be actionable/part
of the “confused” group.
Fromer: every single word in TM is now weird: “secondary
meaning” is both confusing and misleading. The reason is that TM in many
ways has drifted from its narrower and different origins.
Ramsey: Rogers uses the phrase explicitly misleading; both
of those words do work and perhaps allow more rulings as a matter of law.
RT: a word of caution: in false advertising, courts found it
necessary to reinvent exceptions to false/misleading distinction, resulting in
the doctrine of falsity by necessary implication: both the Rogers title v title
exception and the terrible result in Gordon v. Drape are essentially trying to
do that, the latter in a much less coherent way.
Lemley: Heightened standard for confusion is another way to
say that—a sufficiently high number of people, even if not everyone, are going
to be fooled.
RT: the problem is that LOC factors are really bad,
including surveys, so a heightened standard won’t do much good unless you use
different factors. One possibility: a double identity-type rule where same mark/same
goods=necessary implication, which fits the examples in Rogers and Gordon v.
Drape. This would be another way of handling what I’ve called speaker
deception, a narrower concept than Lanham Act source identification.
Lemley: but that gives you no way to handle the Borden v.
Borden situation [which I am not trying to solve]; once you’re past literal
falsity, we’re then looking for a standard about what’s close enough and that’s
difficult.
RT: Ambiguity is the touchstone in Lanham Act false
advertising case: the D must convince the court that there’s at least one
reasonable non-false interpretation of the claim at issue, and if so we move
out of literal falsity into misleadingness.
Ramsey: We could cover false statements and statements that
mislead as to source. [but what does source mean?] She would define source more
narrowly, but would then have to decide what to do w/a survey that said 15% of
consumers thought P was the source.
Mid-Point Discussants: Jeremy Sheff
Amicus efforts: are they doing what we want? [Cue Taylor Swift reference.]
What else should we be doing if that’s not enough: drafting instructions? Other
forms of education?
Stacey Dogan: begins teaching TM with hypotheticals, trying
to draw out students’ ideas of affirmative goals in recognizing/enforcing rights
+ countervailing concerns. Every single factual context we encounter in the
course uses this paradigm: argument in favor of recognition versus countervailing
concerns. We’ve lost that balancing, but every single TM doctrine should consider
that balancing. Think about that with an eye towards stakeholders: purchasers,
citizens, consumers of speech, creators and speakers, competitors (we often think
of them in their role as providing better or cheaper products in particular markets,
but there’s a broader way of thinking of them as contributing to a creative and
dynamic innovation system).
We’re troubled by analytical incoherence, but we should
focus on what costs the system is imposing on these stakeholders. Antimonopoly
movement is giving us a model right now: openness to thinking critically about
our version of capitalism. Color and shape of drugs as assisting elderly
patients know which drugs to take when: example of the kind of evidence of
costs associated w/TM rights. We shouldn’t just be reactionaries but embrace an
affirmative theory of TM law that isn’t based on the early 20th
century but that is more responsive/reflective of current commercial markets.
Bob Bone: We have theories but not agreement on them. TM as
an institution can’t do everything; we should consider the core features of the
institution. Knowing that something is anachronistic doesn’t tell you what to
do about it. Strategy is extremely important.
Lemley: Assuming we don’t get to rewrite the statute, we
should think about what to do instead.
Antitrust is one place; right to repair movement that might get some
bipartisan support as well as substantial business opposition. People
understand what it is to have something break and not to be able to fix it.
Dovetails perfectly w/some aspects of TM reform. Environmental movement is
another possibility: one thing that the response to climate change will involve
is reaction against mindless consumerism, and there are ways to harness that
for coalitions, or at least for persuasive arguments.
RT: Dogan’s contribution makes me think about the effects of
doing balancing internally to a doctrine v. adding defenses: Florabama case is
a really intriguing example of the potential difference where the court’s view,
and especially the concurrence, frames the question as interference with a
speech right first, making balancing unlikely to occur or, if it occurs, to
weigh in favor of the TM claimant. Rogers itself did something a bit different:
it engaged in categorical balancing of First Amendment & TM rights and then
announced a replacement test. The Ninth Circuit followed suit, as did the 11th.
Rogers as defense after infringement is
found, by contrast, would seem likely to behave very differently—once you have
already decided there was infringement, excusing it seems harder; same thing is
what destroyed descriptive fair use in the 9th Circuit on remand
from KP Permanent.
Dogan: This is a very subtle distinction but worth
considering: even rule-based doctrines may reflect balancing even if they don’t
call for balancing within the individual case, and that’s what we should think
about presenting.
Linford: humans may be wired to think of free riding as
unfair. Language of unfair competition invites those common intuitions.
McKenna: right of repair, first sale are good places to look
for intuitions/coalitions about what is fair competition. Courts don’t just
follow the empirical evidence; there’s deep normativity in these doctrines even
if they aren’t self-conscious; implicitly sometimes courts limit the universe of
confusion, especially in first sale and nominative fair use—that’s categorical balancing.
It has built in structure that tips the balance strongly in favor of speech but
isn’t a free pass. Reminding courts that categorical rather than retail
balancing is often the best path is a good approach.
Bone: part of the rejection of rules is the fear of firms
strategically responding to the rule—e.g., a TM use requirement in Rescuecom—and
abusing it. He thinks we can respond to abuse of the rule in the future, but
courts clearly do want to threaten liability in the existing standard rather
than dealing with abuses as they arise. [I think this is related to my point
about asymmetric design against abuse: the fear is almost always of the imagined
infringer, not the abusive TM claimant.]
Fourteenth Trademark Scholars’ Roundtable: Are Key Trademark and Unfair Competition Doctrines Anachronistic?
UCLA School of Law
Mark Janis: 1st day of TM: students’ experience
of brands as used by owners & 3rd parties is so disconnected
from the historical traditions of TM. Anachronism may give away too much by
suggesting the cause of disconnect is the passage of time—that might not be true
or might be partly true. Or is it just the messiness of common law adjudication
+ rapid tech change? Or are these doctrines autonomous—maybe doctrines should
be decoupled from the circumstances of their creation. Disconnect yes,
anachronism maybe.
Session 1: Identifying and Explaining Anachronisms
Introduction: Mark McKenna: Every year, a TM exam could be
written differently: one a very conventional exam question with Company A using
one mark and Company B using a similar mark/similar goods, conventional walk through
confusion factors in the way the test was designed to deal with. Or you can
write an exam about the stuff actually in the news, which is often not a model
the LOC factors were meant for—uses on Instagram, collaborations with artists,
etc. We may be teaching a doctrine modeled on commercial activity that doesn’t
take up much of the space of the way people use TMs. Are our doctrinal tools
workable for the conflicts that arise? JDPI amicus
brief was describing how LOC factors were not developed for these kinds of
cases. Not just for likely confusion, but also use as a mark. Collapse of
separate body of unfair competition, but also old-fashioned ways of thinking
what it means to use as a mark—a certain kind of way of expecting products to
be introduced to the market, that is no longer reflective of lots of stuff that
goes on, especially digitally. Is merchandising really the outlier or is it now
really the model of TM law. So we looked for doctrinally linked pairs of cases
that highlight different commercial practices/evolution of doctrine over time.
How tightly are they connected and do they reflect same doctrine/different circumstances
or something else? E.g. LTTB v. Redbubble v. the Abercrombie spectrum.
Jessica Silbey: doctrinal tools that become less useful over
time b/c of unforeseen developments: LOC factors, Abercrombie spectrum. Is it a
tool that’s lost utility or just a tool that shouldn’t be used in specific
circumstances? What causes us to use old tools in new situations? It’s a
problem of legal reasoning, not just common law—the way we argue cases is to
apply old tools to new situations. Is
there something special about TM? Combo of statutory law layered with multifactor
tests might make these tools stickier than other areas of law; where the
statute is clearer, maybe it’s more adaptable.
New facts: Many doctrinal foundations—comparative advertising,
LOC where market structure and expectations of consumer behavior have changed. Think
about where cts have stubbornly refused to recognize the existence of new facts—MSCHF/Vans
case is one of those, where material alteration/first sale doctrine need to be
applied differently b/c the world has changed and the ct refuses to recognizes
that. But Multi Time Machine is recognizing that Brookfield needs to be
changed. What’s the difference (other than circuit)? Lancaster watch/Hamilton
case and Wavy Baby/MSCHF case can’t both be right—that’s either a totally a new
watch and materially altered or neither of them are. Consumer tastes change, rise
of upcycling and customization, are important changed facts.
In con law we attribute doctrinal shifts to ideological/intellectual
shifts—new ways of thinking about industrial organization. Are there things in
TM where we see intellectual shifts like that? The “use” cases maybe, aesthetic
functionality.
Other doctrines developing in parallel: the First Amendment
is the elephant in the room, w/unintended consequences for financial
regulation, public accommodations, etc. Aesthetic functionality,
affiliation/sponsorship now needs to be seen as affected by First Amendment.
Ornamentality exceptions, like LTTB, versus dog toys & shoes, which are not
seen as the same—wrestling with speech v. product v. conduct. Maybe that
collision explains some of these anachronisms.
Are there other doctrines that may be working in the
background? Franchise law, labor law, antitrust law. [Standing?]
Discussants: Dev
Gangjee: If even what counts as an indication of source has changed so much,
must wonder where TM is going b/c of franchises, contractual arrangements and licensing—the
whole guarantee of quality story just doesn’t make sense any more. TM has achieved
context collapse: losing unfair competition and becoming formalist—similarity =
infringement and that’s it. High formalism in EU TM law; AI systems are
measuring only sign similarity and product similarity. Methodology and approach
affects content—multifactor tests are the ultimate rebuke of realism to formalism.
Jeanne Fromer: Doctrines have ossified in unintended ways.
Distinctiveness: Abercrombie gave a shorthand to help categorize marks and protectability/scope
thereof. But it hardened and became
unmoored from “which marks are competitively dangerous to protect”—categories got
their own internal rules and shorthand, such as “a fanciful mark isn’t in the
dictionary” even when it conveys its meaning, often descriptively—Clorox.
Judge Leval did the right thing quite recently in Rise &
Shine v. Pepsico—pulled back and said don’t harden the categories too much.
Even a suggestive mark can have a primary meaning so closely linked to
goods/services that the mark is weak, like RISE for cold coffee. If the
suggestion of a suggestive mark calls up a central feature, while a descriptive
term describes a trivial feature, the suggestive mark can be weaker than the descriptive
one.
Sometimes it’s our doing: as scholars we sometimes understand
things more categorically than courts intend. Brookfield v. MTM cases: you can
agree w/outcomes or not, but decisions are really nuanced. MTM is saying “it’s
about exactly how Amazon presented its search results.” But we tend to say “MTM
killed IIC online” and we shouldn’t understand it that way. There are some
things on Amazon that feel potentially confusing. Self-reflection: ensure we’re
extrapolating correctly and with nuance.
Many of us talk about Rogers in this way as a categorical
rule, but the VIP case shows there’s nuance in those cases that can get lost.
There’s so much more reliance on empirical evidence now than
in the past, and it raises normative v. empirical questions. Relates to
questions like “trademark spaces” and linguistics in TM. Types of
empirical evidence also change—linguistics versus marketplace evidence to
assess genericity. Booking.com’s focus on survey evidence—courts very open to new
evidence, but we ought to think more critically about what each type of evidence
offers and does. Linguistics v. what consumers think v. what’s going on in marketplace.
Smith v. Chanel: readily accepted tradeoffs against consumer
confusion for purposes of speech and competition; Coca-Cola and other cases not
as much. Thinking about anachronisms/path dependencies, it can be helpful to
think about whether we structure something as a defense or part of the
confusion case, and going back and forth can make it easier or harder for a
consideration to matter.
Lemley: don’t assume we’re moving in the right direction.
Many anachronistic cases have been decided in last 20 years. Borden was wrong
and we were right to broaden the concept of confusion, but many things ignore
that changes in the law move people’s perceptions as well. Penn State
merchandising case might seem like an anachronism, but he thinks it’s a great
case.
Rules v. standard: you might say a rule is anachronistic, it’s
easier to identify whether that is so. Before 2020 we had a genericness
doctrine, now we don’t—the rule that you can’t come back from genericide
was a rule and now it’s just gone. If our doctrines our standards, we tend to
think of them in rulified terms, but that’s not how standards work. You look at
datapoints and they might migrate in a particular direction but that doesn’t
mean they’ll all be the same.
Barton Beebe: Intellectual movements—do they have any effect
on TM law? Law and econ of course, but what else has affected TM law as opposed
to TM commentary? Might not look like TM is constantly struggling with tech,
versus © and patent. But: Amazon has basically replaced TM law, and that’s a
tech development. So is the domain name system, which brings principles from
guild world in 1400s into cyberspace. Dawn Donut—2d Circuit has expressed
skepticism but it’s still there—it does seem like it’s from a different era. Assignment
in gross seems anachronistic given the development of licensing. So the larger
Q is to what extent does tech change affect the premises of TM?
TM law doesn’t seem to be getting better; we don’t have a
whiggish history of progress. Is that lack of progress producing the anachronisms?
Jake Linford: First Amendment Lochnerism—used as a deregulatory
move can happen on a number of different fronts. Worried about trusting 1A to
do good work here. Contract law: recently, Adidas decided Ye was too toxic to
work with and cancelled deal. If I have a shoe brand and want to collaborate
w/some artists and not others. To the extent that contract law has let parties
decide in whom they want to place business trust, Nike can tell MSCHF thanks
but no thanks. But that opens some 1A space to ask whether Nike is exercising rights
in ways implicated by 1A. Generally private action doesn’t count for 1A
purposes, but there is pressure on that [because courts are enforcing the
claimed right of Nike to control whether you can modify a shoe without a
contract].
Rules save resources in a resource-constrained world;
Abercrombie can be ok if it’s right most of the time—does it save us time in
most cases? Does the equitable power of courts provide enough flexibility to
know when to vary the rule? [That sounds like describing a standard, though,
especially given litigation incentives, as Glynn Lunney has written.]
If we don’t have surveys, what do we have? His prelim
research suggests a lot of judicial notice and a parade of individual witnesses
on both sides. Maybe a good survey economizes that march of the witnesses in a
way we like. Without a particular tool, what should we replace it with?
Jeremy Sheff: Existence, nature and scope of judicial
discretion: a broader ideology that has a huge effect on TM cases. If judges
are supposedly just calling balls & strikes, the opinion will write a
certain way. In Judge Leval’s time, judges were judges in that they exercised judgment
and discretion as part of their function. That’s one way intellectual movements
about jurisprudence can shape TM. TM law in EU has moved to more formalistic
application of criteria rather than equitable judgment of unfair competition—a similar
shift.
Other battle lines: First Amendment as deregulatory weapon.
That’s the obverse of another aspect of judging: role of judiciary in social
regulation generally, and whether private power ought to be subject to
countervailing power in federal courts. That will affect TM too but not b/c it’s
a philosophy of TM.
Bob Bone: In torts, we have common-law greats like Judge Traynor
who are willing to innovate—strict liability, etc—in response to broader
changes in general values. We don’t seem to have that in TM—less sensitivity to
external changes; moves like molasses. Why is that? One reason may be lawyers. Practitioners
wrote on TM in the early 20th century: Rogers, Callman, Schechter; part
of the broader intellectual world but also as practicing lawyers maybe more
constrained. As we get more specialized in our practices, maybe that is
affecting ability of doctrine to respond to circumstances.
While costs of TM expanded, the benefits are expanded as
well—changes in the way we view the benefits of marks. TM protection as
creating incentives, or protecting property like ©. Why? Lawyers are using TM
law to fill gaps. Doctrines that served a different purpose originally can be
repurposed to do that.
Lisa Ramsey: Divide on Rogers: 9th Circuit uses
it as a replacement for standard confusion test; SDNY in Metabirkins: use LOC
test first, then have jury apply 1A defense. That might change the outcome if
the factfinder first finds infringement and then decides whether there’s any
defense.
McKenna: Shift to textualism: JDPI briefing, the attempt to claim
you can find answers in the text of the Lanham Act, which is obviously bonkers
and yet the audience is open to it (compare Star Athletica). Tort: Different
courts often have different normative goals: some are more interested in
compensation for injured Ps, some in incentives where P is just a tool, some in
punishing bad actors. Teaching torts alongside TM, one striking difference is how
much TM pretends it’s just finding stuff in nature in commercial practice and
following consumers—hides the inevitable normativity of the various choices.
[Indeed, where did we get the rule that 15% confusion is a lot?] We’ve been
fighting about the ultimate endpoint of following what consumers do, which
seems to be rights in gross. Any kind of arrangement is conceivable now. Brand
owners are doing things to themselves we used to think we wouldn’t do. It’s
getting harder to present to courts that not everything that allocates value to
TM owners is good. TM has its own reasons and internal limits that aren’t just
derived from what we see in the world.
Chris Sprigman: Came to TM through competition/antitrust. 40
years ago a lot of federal judges thought antitrust was more important than TM
and so many judges saw TMs as anticompetitive; now many of them don’t. Antitrust
is the polar opposite of TM in openness to ideological revolutions; complete
(but shallow) reassessment of relationship b/t TM and competition.
Neo-Brandeisians haven’t focused on TM, but are getting there, and they may find
that the 1930s and 40s writing will seem correct: TMs are more a force for
oligopoly than for innovation, which might then affect antitrustàfederal
judiciary since antitrust lawyers are elite lawyers and TM lawyers aren’t.
Nuance is overrated in law (contra Fromer): Antitrust understands
that deeply and used to eschew nuance even more. If two bodegas decide to fix
the price at which they sell Diet Coke, their operators go to jail. That’s a
correct result! First Amendment tests: they should largely eschew nuance, as 9th
Circuit did with Rogers; 2d Cir. did too in Rogers itself, which was misunderstood
b/c in Twin Peaks both sides had First Amendment interests—the first line of
Twin Peaks is that it involves the exception to Rogers. Misunderstood by dcts
that don’t have a ton of time. Nuance is the enemy, not the ally; breathing
space under the 1A is not an anachronism. We shouldn’t have trials over intent
or whether an Eveready test shows 19% confusion or 38% (as it did in Rogers).
There are arguments on both sides, but that’s the real problem w/anachronism as
a framing device—it’s useful, but normative Qs always proceed it.
Robert Burrell: If the claim is that ossification has led to
TM’s misshapenness—not true in UK b/c TM keeps responding to calls for
modernization—law fears being left behind state of commerce, advertising
practices. Robust TM use doctrine in 1920s was swept away in 1938 b/c 1927
courts didn’t appreciate the hugely significant rise of advertising which would
harm TM owners unless stamped out. Time and again, the harm to the shape of TM
law has been caused by demand to “reflect commercial reality” and protect “brands”
rather than TMs. Assignments in gross are a good example. UK TM law is not good
b/c it got rid of the prohibition on assignment in gross; we need more
anachronisms. The internet is a partial exception—there has been an ECJ commitment
not to break the internet, which means that pushing back against TM expansionism
has also been done in the name of modernity.
Stacey Dogan: What gets called law & econ is often
libertarianism/view of world as adulation of commercially successful
individuals and disdain for community/anti-communitarianism. That’s influenced
every aspect of our law for the past few decades. Fluid/flexible legal
standards allow judges to be influenced by that. Successful people shouldn’t
pay taxes! It’s all part of the same view.
Can’t start from scratch b/c law has reciprocally influenced
commercial reality. But what would a rebuild from the ground up, starting with
today’s commerce, look like? Chris Leslie says a big problem of antitrust is
not a problem w/frame, but that courts have simply ignored the facts b/c of
their framework. We could try to bring anticompetitive effects forward.
Mike Grynberg: TM is pluralist in a way a lot of us don’t
like. Anti-free-riding impulse will always be with us. LTTB is different b/c
plaintiff looked more like a free rider (on the aesthetic meaning). Always been
with us: there was a 2 Justice dissent in Kellog v. Nabisco. Old cases were also
shorter and easier to read—there weren’t multiple steps to run through. It’s
not just that we have ossified structures, but we have structures upon structures—in
Borden, the court says the label is fine and does the multifactor test. In
2016, the Second Circuit says do multifactor test + NFU factors. As Tushnet
says, “TM law never gets less complicated.”
Laura Heymann: district courts fear reversal; they want to
be safe and claim calling balls and strikes, unlike Justice Traynor on the Cal.
SCt.
Consider also how PTO examiners are trained. TMEP purports
to instruct them; they’re often cutting and pasting from TMEP or prior office
actions. Maybe that’s inherent to an admin system. Consistency, predictability,
not rocking the boat is a value in the system, which may bubble up.
Mid-Point Discussants: Rebecca Tushnet
[I think that’s not true—700,000 applications a year can’t
produce consistency, and also most Art. III judges have no idea what
registration is and just guess at its general meaning.]
Figure skating, poetry, intermural speech and debate, and
law: what do these fields have in common? Development of elaborate internal systems
that are often impenetrable to outsiders but that make sense to insiders to
distinguish good from bad performances. An aesthetics of law is often,
today, cashed out in a multifactor or multistep test—I think that occurred in
formalism too, even if what we now call factors were instead presented as a
decision tree.
Carol Rose, Crystals and Mud,
a tendency for law to grow more rococo until the legislature or someone else
w/authority steps in and tries something new, which then accretes its own
apparatus that allows explanation; criticisms of formalism can now be applied to
legal realism (accretion of multifactor tests—2d Circuit as case in point where
for nominative fair use they just say “throw it into the pot” and also say
every factor has to be considered in every case, except maybe Rogers cases).
Con law concepts: Reva
Siegel & Jack Balkin: preservation through transformation. The doctrine
has the same name but considers different types of evidence and thus produces
different results. Often works to scientize a doctrine. The Brandeis brief is a
good example: by claiming scientific, empirical support it contributed to the
idea that that’s what government always needs to justify its decision to regulate,
which might be a good change but is definitely different than it was
before.
Larger problem w/ TM system as a system of law is its lack
of adversarial design: design with assumption that people are going to be
pressing the boundaries in asserting claims (Glynn Lunney’s work on degeneration
of TM doctrine)—there’s a consensus of the powerful about whose claims are
dangerous (class actions—CAFA; prisoners—AEDPA; securities plaintiffs—PLSRA).
The only recent recognition of incentives to exploit the law in TM law is the
change from some circuits recognizing niche fame to being told not to do that
in the TDRA plus a little bit of greater cancellation options; the TMA went in
the other direction, rewarding aggressive claims w/the threat of
injunction, on irreparable harm. Maybe it is time to try to put TM into the
larger progressive antimonopoly discussion.
Abercrombie v. LTTB: Use as a mark’s absence has led to a
realignment around informational/decorative to take things out of the category “arbitrary.”
Abercrombie notes “the same term may be put to different uses with respect to a
single product” w/r/t descriptive uses, but not other types of uses. Should
secondary meaning defeat that? Lizzo’s 100% THAT BITCH suggests yes in
practice; what about in theory? After Booking.com, yes in theory seems like the
courts’ likely answer.
Another thing in Abercrombie we don’t talk about: “It need
hardly be added that fanciful or arbitrary terms enjoy all the rights accorded
to suggestive terms as marks without the need of debating whether the term is ‘merely
descriptive’ and with ease of establishing infringement.” That’s probably the
wrongest thing the case said from a current perspective—that’s not a LOC
multifactor analysis.
One more background doctrine to add to Silbey’s list:
Article III standing. To answer Beebe’s question: Dawn Donut is now obviously a
standing doctrine. Likewise, free riding may not provide Article III standing, which
purports to require harm.
Bill McGeveran: The source/brand distinction which seems so
rigorous to us seems bizarre to TM claimants. The people whose interests TM serves
don’t agree that TM is for source identification; they like that too, but that’s
not what they think TM is for—it’s much more important to understand that “Apple”
means cool and functional. Is this a new fact? It’s evolved more and more in
this direction.
Shift in what progressivism around economics is in
policy. FTC might ban noncompetes! Very rapid shift in policy as well as
intellectual approaches. The world of possibility around legal change in
TM-adjacent fields is much higher than it has been in a long time. Income
inequality; perception of campaigns controlled by economic interests.
Realignment also possible around speech interests. 1A plays a different role in
TM than in other regulatory, anti-admin state moves. The villain here is large
corporations/TM bullies.
Leah Grinvald: Studying caselaw isn’t the whole picture:
lots happens outside of the courtroom. Amazon is a huge case in point; Google
as well; Jim Gibson’s piece on rights accretion—affects what cases are brought,
fought, settled.
Silbey: What prevents TM lawyers from bringing in arguments
about identity politics, or art history, and not just branding literature?
Metabirkins judge rejected art historian for having no methodology; sociology
and urban planning were disputed methodologies in early 20th century
[and perhaps still, to CJ Roberts]. Became available to lawyers; what is
preventing TM law from adopting other forms of empirical evidence to make
arguments for Ps and Ds? Are we seeing claims adjoined to TM that suggest
related problems, the way we’re now seeing © and privacy claims brought
together? Maybe not b/c TM is already so capacious. [TM and ROP, maybe.]
Sheff: Most TM cases aren’t worth enough to litigate complex
issues of expertise—they won’t destroy a business (except for Rogers-type
cases). Changing the name is often an option, and if that cost is less than the
cost of expert litigation that would affect choices. Silbey: surveys are
expensive. Sheff: Ds often don’t use them, and at least they’re relatively
formalized now.
Crystals and Mud is a good comparator: we might have to adapt
to new developments. We can adopt exceptions—separate bright line rules: one
fact causes us to switch to a different path. Rogers is one example. But the
alternative is to just throw it into a multifactor hopper. The 1A implications
suggest that move is inappropriate in certain categories of cases. That’s more
a prophylactic rule than a standard. Some injuries are simply more important
than others.
The Polaroid factors are actually dicta; resolved on
laches grounds. Second Circuit is thinking about how close two products need to
be; they need not be identical, but here are a bunch of things to think about
w/related but non-identical products; but anyway P loses on laches grounds. We’re
treating this list as the definition of how we know when two businesses
are going to be confused. Similarly with Abercrombie, which purports to
give shape to the category of suggestive marks, the court traces through some
common-law development; even if a mark isn’t descriptive, and even if it’s not
a technical TM, it might be registrable/protectable—Abercrombie allocates it to
the side of arbitrary/fanciful marks. Those are moves that differ in
implications for how that doctrine will be picked up in future cases in ways
courts don’t anticipate.
Fromer: Don’t forget role of PTO and other agencies, either
contributing to ossification or development of TM. A lot of what they do is
responsive to courts, but they’re at the front end of granting registration.
They’re not creating protection (they say), but deciding to grant or deny
registrations does mean they deal w/businesses thinking about TM rights. They
see a lot of situations that TM law will ultimately have to contend with [as
they first noticed the decorative/ornamental flood].
In many ways PTO is very bad at responding to new
situations, though in some very forward-looking. They’ve been very permissive
about allowing businesses to rebrand/do brand extensions in ways the courts
haven’t noticed but affects what happens in TM. Permissive in allowing token
uses to count as use in commerce. They’re pretty bad at catching descriptiveness
w/o secondary meaning. But for failure to function, they’ve really been
prominent b/c the PTO was willing to act. It’s unfortunate they have a
framework of “applicants are our customers” and “we want more registrations
every year.” A lot turns on the data that they do keep and use when searching.
They have no general database of specimens, for example; that might keep TM in
the past/enable businesses to keep registering the same thing over and over
again. They don’t search beyond the registration database.
Lemley: (1) list of cases/juxtapositions—with 1-2 exceptions,
every anachronism doctrine is a doctrine that expanded TM rights to a category
of things that didn’t exist traditionally. (2) we’re at a generational
disconnect. Nobody thinks about brands the way TM scholars think about TM.
Spent much of his life resisting that effort, but we also need to say “a new
theory needs new rules.” RT’s point about standing doctrine: always good to see
a dumb doctrine defeated by a dumber doctrine. But there are other ways to
think about what that new theory might do that can free us from existing
doctrinal constraints. Maybe consumer confusion doesn’t matter at all; at a
minimum it’s not determinative. If brands aren’t TMs, then confusion might not
matter. Maybe we don’t need a presumption of exclusivity in a particular market.
And then the 1A might come in: there’s no special exemption from the 1A that
stems from misleading commercial speech b/c that train has left the station.
Maybe we should welcome the idea that every TM case is one that needs a 1A analysis.
Consider a rhetoric of rights on the user side as a counterbalance:
not a brand totally owned by company, but a thing that the world benefits from;
a right to choose whether I want that meaning or another one.
Dev Gangjee: Are we going back to some ur-text that is
disconnected from “normal people”—but advertising has been fundamentally
rethought as a good thing these days. Look at greenwashing/sustainability
agenda: if TM is hitched to advertising, we can talk to others and connect that
to the larger agenda. We’re not wrong in being cautious about this trend, and we
don’t have to concede that society has moved on. Ralph Brown’s piece on
advertising and the public interest: The FTC used to be the site of many of
these debates, including about whether TMs could be misleadingly suggestive.
On Lemley’s point about new rules: EU adopted new theories
and got terrible rules—just mushed them all together and invented harms.
Linford: Thomas could get a textualist test out of 43(a). Are
Amazon & Walmart the villains w/aggressive tactics, or is that just
competition that we love b/c it offers low prices? Amazon is worse for
consumers than it was 10 years ago; we had an opportunity in MTM to do better—just
tell consumers you don’t have an MTM watch, just one line of code. Once we don’t
ask even that, the floodgates of enshittification open. [This strikes me as quite
wrong—Amazon’s a bunch worse b/c the product results are controlled by how much
the sellers pay Amazon, and it’s especially bad when you aren’t looking
for a specific brand—the problem is on the seller side, not the consumer side.]
McKenna: Why do people think TM’s role is to protect brands?
Prestonettes: the complaint was that D was interfering with what we want known
about our brand, and the Court said that wasn’t its job. The word is not taboo!
What enabled this shift even among TM lawyers? Courts say all the time, TM law
promotes competition—but it’s a shift from TM law as a system to trademarks
promote competition, which is a significant move that enables you to stop thinking
about what the limits of protection should be. TM needs a theory of
competition. It’s not a thing found in nature.
Grynberg: part of the PTO’s problem is that it’s under the
Fed Cir’s thumb and trying to survive what the Fed Cir thinks about IP rights.
Burrell: can an admin agency be part of ossification? We
have to think about to what extent PTO rules find their way up to superior
courts. But b/c the PTO deals w/the vast majority of TM disputes, that’s the
wrong Q—they can be their own source of ossification for their own disputes.
Can admin agencies resist attempts to deossify from the courts? Sometimes you
can see them deliberately ignoring dilettantes on courts, watering down their
rules.
Sprigman: if TM is going to reconsider how TMs shape competition,
it shouldn’t ID retail-level villains; it should develop a theory about what
competition is supposed to do and how rules should shape it. Mishakawa: a TM is
designed to induce people to think they want something—to differentiate markets
that were competitive and create artificial differentiation to move the market
more towards oligopoly. That’s a gigantic idea, and not about whether Walmart
or Amazon is bad or good. The Chicago model celebrates limitless product
differentiation, w/no margin of diminishing returns. That’s a contestable
understanding of what’s good about markets. Sometimes we standardize! E.g.,
financial markets. Efficiencies come from standardization. Henry Smith also
writes about this for property. TM law needs to find that level of what we’re
looking for in general, not on a case by case basis, which would just be more
ad hoc.
Bone: Normative anachronisms, not just doctrinal ones. And
anachronisms about empirical world. Useful to distinguish among ways tools/beliefs
can be anachronistic. Abercrombie is a good example of doctrinal anachronism.
In Polaroid, Judge Friendly was trying to resolve a tension in 2d Circuit and a
typical way to do that is to say everyone’s right; we do that by taking what
everyone cares about and sticking it into a multifactor test. It only gets
worse as time goes by. Abercrombie is similar: Judge Friendly says let’s look
at the categories, but the old categories were supported by a different
normative theory (technical TMs—a natural law property right that was dominant
during the conceptualist period), so we kept categories that were ill-suited to
the new normative baseline. Not surprising it’s a mess. But it’s not as bad a
mess as LOC because we can look at some of these categories and say it makes sense
to have categories, but they’re not the right lines because we’re all
functionalists now and want to know what the categories are for.
Ramsey: the challenge for judges who don’t see many TM cases:
what are they supposed to do? If we don’t have a multifactor test for the
traditional cases, what should we be doing? We need a framework for argument.
Sprigman: normatively, do we want consumers’ own savvy to
take care of this?
Bone: we used to have that—double identity/technical TMs
were a much easier confusion test.
Beebe: Neo-Brandeisian approach to IIC might be that it’s fine thing unless it’s
bait and switch; not clear how it would think about post-sale confusion.
Fashion brands distract us from the giant world of everyday TMs; how do we
navigate that gravitational pull distracting us from competition theory.
Lemley: we could try a double non-identity test: not the
same field and not the same mark, we’re done. We’d have to decide how close you
could get. We’d also have to cut back on sponsorship/affiliation to do that. It’s
not a reconceptualization that requires a return to the past, though that might
be a component: there might be a universe of ordinary TM disputes from 80 years
ago where the old rules are fine, and then a universe of brand disputes that
could just be treated differently; the theory of competition there is
fundamentally different.
Thursday, February 23, 2023
Site news: cross posting to Wordpress seems down, but email subscription is here
Amicus in Jack Daniels v. VIP
I'm filing an amicus today on behalf of First Amendment scholars:
Enrique Armijo, Professor of Law, Elon University School of
Law
Lisa Pondrom Ramsey, Professor of Law, University of San
Diego School of Law
Rebecca Tushnet, Frank Stanton Professor of First Amendment
Law, Harvard Law School
John Villasenor, Professor of Law and Electrical
Engineering, UCLA; Founder and Faculty Co-Director, UCLA Institute for
Technology, Law and Policy
Eugene Volokh, Gary T. Schwartz Distinguished Professor of
Law, UCLA School of Law
Catching up: Meta wins (one) infringement claim about its rebrand on motion to dismiss
Dfinity Found. v. Meta Platforms, Inc., 2022 WL 16857036, No. 22-cv-02632-CRB (N.D. Cal. Nov. 10, 2022)
Dfinity alleged that Meta infringed its Dfinity and Rainbow
marks in its rebranding. The court granted a motion to dismiss on lack of
likely confusion.
Dfinity is a nonprofit organization that runs the Internet
Computer, a public blockchain network. Dfinity seeks to “provid[e] millions of
developers and entrepreneurs with a public compute platform—creating a
revolutionary new way to build websites, enterprise systems and internet
services within an open environment.” Users can download “dapps” (or
decentralized applications) which allow users to design and develop software
using the Internet Computer blockchain. Dfinity’s website also provides users
with “educational tutorials and courses in the field of distributed computing
platforms.” Dfinity sponsors conferences and hackathons, and gives in-person
and virtual presentations. In 2021, Dfinity announced its Developer Grant
Program, a grant fund of $200 million “to support initiatives for developers to
work on the Internet Computer.”
In 2018, Dfinity secured registration for its Dfinity mark for use in various computer-based services, including: “Computer software for decentralized platforms, namely, software for using a consensus engine incorporating blockchain technology for securing data with cryptographic information”; “Design and development of computers and software”; and “Hosting of digital content on the Internet, namely, computerized data, files, applications and information.” Color was not claimed as a feature of the mark:
infinity sign with left loop larger than right with DFINITY beneath
In 2021, it secured registration of its second mark, the
Rainbow Mark. The colors purple, pink, blue, orange, and yellow are claimed as
a feature of the Rainbow Mark, and Dfinity’s usage guidelines require that
these precise colors be used:
a more equal infinity sign in different colors on its own |
In 2022, Meta sought registration of its new MetamMark, described as “a geometric design consisting of two loops.” Meta employs it in a variety of ways, including on its website, social media channels, and products:
Dfinity also alleged uses of specific “multi-colored
versions” of the Meta Mark:
the infinity symbol in various colored textures |
After Meta unveiled its new mark in October 2021, users allegedly replied to Dfinity’s Twitter account with comments on the similarities between the Dfinity Marks and the Meta Mark, and possibilities for partnerships or collaboration between the two entities. Dfinity sued for federal and state trademark infringement.
Dfinity mark: Under Ninth Circuit law, “use in commerce”
requires both “(1) an element of actual use, and (2) an element of display.” Dfinity
argued that its registration of its marks gives it “prima facie evidence of
[their] validity,” so it need not plead use in commerce to demonstrate a
protectable ownership interest in an enforcement action. “The Ninth Circuit
does not agree.”
All the specific uses to which Dfinity pointed were uses of
its rainbow mark. Without “any accompanying evidence in the complaint or
incorporated by reference,” the mere allegation that the mark was used in
commerce was too bare and conclusory to survive a motion to dismiss, though
Dfinity got leave to amend.
Likely confusion with the rainbow mark: The Ninth Circuit
has cautioned that the Sleekcraft test is “pliant” and that “[s]ome factors are
much more important than others, and the relative importance of each individual
factor will be case-specific.” Courts “must be acutely aware of excessive
rigidity when applying the law in the Internet context; emerging technologies
require a flexible approach.”
Similarity is “one of the most, if not the most, important
factor when assessing likelihood of confusion,” and “similarities [are] weighed
more heavily than differences.”
What was the Meta mark to which Dfinity’s rainbow mark was
to be compared? Dfinity argued that there were “multi-colored versions of” the
Meta mark:
But the source for that allegation was an article called
“Designing our new company brand: Meta” which describes the process of creating
the new mark. “The article includes photos and short videos of the Meta logo in
various stages of transformation, and states that the logo ‘can take on
infinite textures, colors and movement, capturing the creativity and
imagination of a 3D world.’”
None of the photos on the page show
the Meta Mark in the color and shape shown by Dfinity in its complaint and
opposition; rather, it appears that Dfinity’s version of the Meta Mark comes
from a video showing the Meta Mark morphing into different colors, textures,
and shapes before ending on the blue, traditional Meta Mark. Dfinity appears to
have taken a screenshot of the Meta Mark as it mutates in this video, timing
the image to precisely the split second in which it looks most like the Rainbow
Mark. Dfinity has not alleged that this “multi-colored version[ ]” of the Meta
Mark appears anywhere else but in the video in this article.
The court agreed with Meta the proper comparator was the one
registered as a trademark and that appeared on its webpages and products. “Even assuming the design story is a
commercial use of Meta’s trademark—describing the company’s brand evolution
from Facebook to Meta and thus related to the goods and services the new brand
seeks to market and sell—the use of the screenshotted multi-colored mark is so
fleeting that it cannot be a source of customer confusion.”
main Meta mark in blue |
Once that was set, the marks were dissimilar. “Dfinity’s shape is a traditional infinity sign, with the lines crossing at the horizontal and vertical midpoint, and a precise multicolor format that Dfinity instructs users of the logo not to alter. While Meta’s logo can and does appear in different colors, and is not always in the traditional blue, its shape is still dissimilar to Dfinity’s.”—more like an “M” for meta, a video game controller, or a soft pretzel (first two offered by Meta, the last from the court). The marks were even more dissimilar when they are accompanied by the parties’ names, “which happens often (though not always) in commercial settings.” “The thickness of the lines and the general continuous pattern of two loops intersecting at a midpoint” were the only similarities.
Still, that wasn’t enough on its own; they were not “obviously”
dissimilar, or “so facially dissimilar that they cannot possibly create a
likelihood of confusion,” and prior dismissals at the motion to dismiss stage
have relied on “clearly different” words appearing in the accused marks.
“Because, as explained above, both parties occasionally use the marks without
their names attached, words are not dispositive here.”
Thus, the court proceeded to consider the remaining factors.
Strength: The court took judicial notice of 1500 other registered trademarks
comprising an infinity symbol for the same classes of goods and services as Dfinity’s.
That didn’t mean Dfinity’s marks were weak; Meta didn’t show how recognizable
those marks were compared to Dfinity’s. “It is certainly possible that Dfinity
is the most recognizable infinity sign in its class, in which case even a
suggestive mark in a ‘crowded field’ could be stronger than expected.” That’s a
fact issue.
So too with commercial strength. “Dfinity pleads facts that
show some measure of commercial recognition, which is all that is required on a
motion to dismiss.” Given the Ninth Circuit’s description of suggestive marks
like the rainbow mark as “presumptively weak,” the court found the mark neither
particularly weak nor particularly strong, giving this factor little weight at
this stage.
Proximity of goods and services/likelihood of expansion: The
services were not “totally unrelated” enough to be dispositive on a motion to
dismiss. “While Meta does not now provide the precise services that Dfinity
does, it does provide developers and creators with the ability to design,
build, and launch VR apps on Meta Quest.” Given Zuckerberg’s founder’s letter
launching Meta (“The metaverse will not be created by one company. It will be
built by creators and developers making new experiences and digital items that
are interoperable and unlock a massively larger creative economy than the one
constrained by today’s platforms and their policies.”), it was plausible that
Zuckerberg was describing products and services like Dfinity’s Internet
Computer.
While Dfinity targets developers interested in using the
blockchain to “build websites, enterprise systems and internet services within
an open environment,” Meta targets everyone, including developers, “some
of whom presumably are interested in building their products within, or at
least compatible with, such an ‘open environment.’” Meta argued that its closed
products were antithetical to that vision, and that there was no indication
that it was interested in expanding into the realm occupied by the Internet
Computer. “But given Meta’s metamorphosis over the last few years, such a move
is not implausible on the pleadings.”
Type of goods/degree of care: Here Meta did much
better. “[T]he developers to which
Dfinity markets its software are perhaps multitudes more sophisticated [than
ordinary consumers online] and exercise a correspondingly higher degree of
care.” It didn’t matter that Dfinity offered its services “for little or no cost,”
given that they were software services offered to developers. “A service can be
both low-cost and sophisticated, and a tech-savvy consumer is not likely to
exercise less care if the service is sophisticated, simply because it is also
inexpensive…. That these sophisticated people, immersed in the intricacies of
the tech world, would be duped by a logo, particularly one that is not similar
in key respects, borders on implausible.”
Actual confusion: Dfinity offered six Twitter replies as
evidence of actual confusion, though it didn’t link to or plead the contents of
the Dfinity tweet to which they were replying. The replies either state that
the marks resemble each other (“Too similar,” “meta is copying icp’s logo or
something,”) or that the marks’ similarity indicates a partnership between Meta
and Dfinity (“Meta+InternetComputer = ...?” “Partnership?” “I see a
partnership? Kismet?”).
First, the fact that these
statements appear to reply to a tweet from Dfinity itself (regardless of what
it said) indicate that they do not represent the natural confusion of a
consumer; these replies are derived from some prompting from Dfinity itself
rather than experiencing the marks organically as consumers in the marketplace.
Second, as Meta argues, these replies indicate a clear understanding that Meta
and Dfinity represent different entities, and Dfinity’s original tweet prompted
the connection and discussion of similarities between the marks or possible
partnerships.
Similarity of marketing channels: similar, but not of heavy
weight.
Intent: because of the dissimilarities in marks, and without
other allegations of bad faith beyond a general allegation of “willful and
wonton disregard of Dfinity’s established and superior rights” in its
trademark, this factor weighed against finding a likelihood of confusion.
As a whole, the key factors were: (1) the similarity of the
marks; (2) the relatedness of the goods; and (3) the type of goods and degree
of care. Without evidence of the mark’s strength or weakness at this stage, the
court gave heavier weight to the type of goods and their accompanying customer
base, “tech-savvy developers.” “With so sophisticated a product and a customer
base, the type of good and the degree of care should be given more weight in
this analysis than in the usual trademark infringement case, where laypeople
are often the prospective customers.”
Overall, confusion was implausible.